146
Views
0
CrossRef citations to date
0
Altmetric
Research Article

Income per-capita across-countries: stories of catching-up, stagnation, and laggardness

ORCID Icon
Article: 2339701 | Accepted 26 Mar 2024, Published online: 09 May 2024

ABSTRACT

The convergence/divergence debate and plausible explanations to the process of catching-up remain highly controversial research areas in growth economics. Recently, these issues have been the subject of questionable predictions with regard future prospect for backward countries, raising concerns about the right direction of macroeconomic policy. To explore these issues, a sample of 131 countries is studied over the 1950s–2010s to identify those that have managed to catching-up, remain stagnant, or keep lagging further behind. Time-distance to the frontier and productivity decompositions, based on non-parametric methods, suggest that some countries have successfully completed already the caching-up, and it would take between 27 and 194 years for others to do so in the most optimistic scenario. But many others would never do. Policy implications drawn from the comparative analysis suggests the need to strengthen local innovation in order to increase the ability to catching-up alongside widespread reliance on technology diffusion from abroad.

1. Introduction

Whether observed differences in levels of income per capita between rich and poor countries shall disappear or not in the distant future is one of the most intriguing question economists have been faced to since the very beginning of the economics science (Elmslie, Citation1995). Inconditional income convergence across the world economy has been punctually predicted by Lucas (Citation2000) to occur by the end of the twenty-first century, or within some 340 years – according to more cautious prediction by Patel et al. (Citation2021). But some critics have suggested that substantial divergence will continue to exist instead (Chen & Ravallion, Citation2010; P. Johnson & Papageorgiou, Citation2020; Nell, Citation2020).

Seeking a feasible answer to that question, contributing to the empirical debate on the issues of convergence/divergence and hopefully offering new research perspectives in this field, I split the world economies into successful and unsuccessful cases of catching-up and study the roles of technology diffusion from abroad and local innovation in explaining their performance.

In particular, using data from the Penn World Tables, PWT V.10.0 (Feenstra et al., Citation2015),Footnote1 a sample of 131 countries is classified into those at the frontier and those that over long periods of time show patterns consistent with catching-up, stagnation, or laggardness. The classification is based on records of income per-capita relative to the frontier over the 1950s–2010s and adjusted growth gaps, calculated by subtracting the growth rate of the countries at the frontier from the growth rate of other countries.

To provide a plausible explanation of the key determinants of catching-up, productivity decompositions based on well-established non-parametric techniques are used. This approach is aimed to factor productivity changes that are related to technical changes (associated to the diffusion of best practice technologies worldwide) and efficiency changes which are assumed to capture local innovativeness (Coelli et al., Citation2005; Kumar & Russell, Citation2002; Los & Timmer, Citation2005).

A remarkable result of this methodological shift that challenges the conclusions about the future posed by the influential research of some economists (Kremer et al., Citation2022; Lucas, Citation2000; Patel et al., Citation2021; Roy et al., Citation2016; Spence, Citation2011) is that even among the select group of succesful catching-up countries, convergence would take not less than three decades, and as much as 200 years in the most optimistic scenario. In turn, countries that are secularly stagnant would take not least that seven decades but as much as 2000 years to get there. And countries that keep lagging behind would need not less than 500 years in the best case, but more probably will never do it.

The paper continues as follows: in Section 2, I provide a brief review of related literature. In Section 3 the proposed four-types of countries classification is introduced. In Section 4, the growth gaps of countries behind the frontier is analyzed. In Section 5, a procedure to calculate the years needed to catching-up is developed. In Section 6, unconditional β-convergence analysis is conducted and related to the convergence clubs debate. In Section 7, the relative importance of local innovation and technology diffusion to explain the catching-up performance is studied. Section 8, provides some concluding remarks.

2. A review of the literature

Research in the field of growth economics has been marked by two closely interconnected debates: the convergence/divergence issue and the role of technology diffusion and innovation in this context.

The first of these debates is anything but new, yet it remains unsettled. Traced back at least to an old controversy between Hume Citation1742 and Tucker Citation1776—regarded in fact as one of the first major doctrinal debates on economic thought well in advance of Adam Smith’s inquiry about the Wealth of Nations (Elmslie Citation1995)—this was also a central issue in Veblen’s (Citation1915 account of what Gerschenkron (Citation1962 later famously referred to as the “advantage of backwardness”.

Throughout the second half of the twentieth century, the Neoclassical model sparked anew controversy that weakened the credibility on the probability of absolute (unconditional) convergence and led instead the issues of conditional convergence, catching-up and divergence to draw research interest from the mid-1980s onwards (Abramovitz, Citation1986; Barro & Sala-I-Martin, Citation1997; Baumol, Citation1986; Fagerberg, Citation1995; Pritchett, Citation1997; Romer, Citation1986). Initially related to differential rates of capital accumulation, the disagreement turned then towards the ability of less developed countries to adopt the technology – namely the inventions and ideas – of the countries at the frontier (Mankiw et al., Citation1995; Romer, Citation1993).

From the beginning of the twenty-first century and until recently, some notorious contributions have made it clear that the fundamental disagreement is still open. Lucas (Citation2000) boldly predicted that “unconditional convergence” would be a fact of reality by 2100, and his optimistic prediction have received timely support (Kremer et al., Citation2022; Patel et al., Citation2021; Roy et al., Citation2016; Spence, Citation2011). Barro (Citation2015) also predicts convergence but in the conditional sense (and Nell, Citation2020 refutes it).

On the other side of the controversy, there are researchers who point out that what has been observed is divergence instead (Chen & Ravallion, Citation2010; Goldstone, Citation2002; P. Johnson & Papageorgiou, Citation2020; Pomeranz, Citation2000). More in line with the results found below, Pritchett (Citation2000b) suggests that some countries appear to catching-up (hills) while others stagnate (plains) and others show steady declines (valleys).

That there is substantial heterogeneity in cross-country patterns of income and economic growth is generally accepted. What seems much more contentious is the conclusion drawn by some researchers about a “new era of unconditional convergence” which rely on recent trend-shifts in the data. By revisiting the data and focusing on longer periods of time, the findings below support that story for a selected group of catching-up countries. But also give support to alternative stories of stagnation and divergence.

Among other explanations for the substantial heterogeneity that is observed across countries, technology differences (Easterly & Levine, Citation2000) and differences in efficiency in the use of technology (Clark & Feenstra, Citation2003) continue to be particularly controversial. A crucial issue in this discussion is whether the technology attribute that allows poor countries to catching-up is made exclusively of the inventions and knowledge developed at the frontier or there is room for endogenous innovation (Fagerberg et al., Citation2010).

For some economists, the interaction of technology diffusion and indigenous absortive capabilities is the key to explain why there are some countries that manage to catching-up and others that fail to do so (Ayerst et al., Citation2023; Cai et al., Citation2022; Comin & Hobijn, Citation2010; Comin & Nanda, Citation2019; Park & Dreamson, Citation2023; Pérez-Trujillo & Lacalle-Calderon, Citation2020; Sebbesen, Citation2023; Stokey, Citation2015). For others, local innovation, and therefore the institutions and incentive structures designed to boost it, is the key mechanism (Kunieda et al., Citation2021; Malerba & Lee, Citation2020; Pandey et al., Citation2022; Perilla, Citation2019, Citation2020; Tomizawa et al., Citation2020). The evidence below appears to favour the latter view.

3. Backward countries’ relative levels of income

The World Bank four-tier classification between Low Income (LICs), Lower Middle Income (LMICs), Upper Middle Income (UMICs) and High Income Countries (HICs) remains a well-established standard that allows to gain quick knowledge on the diversity of cross-country income per-capita levels. Unfortunately, this ranking does not allow, per se, to judge the ability – and indeed the probability – of countries behind to shortening the distance to the frontier. This probability depends positively on the economic performance of countries behind. But, it is inversely related to the economic performance of the leading countries.

It seems staggering, for instance, that by 1997, the year that India graduated to the LMICs, it had roughly the same relative income (PPP-adjusted) than in 1975 (8% relative to the OECD countries). This was lower than the average in previous decades (10% over the 1950s–1970s). And over the 2010s this country had more or less the same relative income than during the 1950s. In contrast, Egypt was roughly stagnant and below the performance of India over the 1950s–1980s (relative income of 7%). But Egypt reached a relative income of 16% by the end of the 1990s, and around 25% during the 2010s. The contrary happened to Guinea whose relative income averaged 20% over the 1960s–1970s, but fell down steadily to around 10% through the following two decades, and over the 2010s fell further below 5%.

To make sense of this diversity in the catching-up experience across countries, below a sample of 131 countries is classified into those at the frontier, and those that over the 1950s–2010s have managed to catching-up, remained stagnant, or kept lagging further behind.Footnote2 Furthermore, depending on data availability, countries are split into time clusters.Footnote3

The classification is based on 10-year averages.Footnote4 The benchmark is formed by 24 countries members of the OECD since before the 1990s.Footnote5 These are referred now on as frontier countries (FRCs). Relative incomes are calculated as the ratio between a country’s average and the average at the FRCs. For instance, through the 1950s average income was US$3732 in Colombia, US$1208 in South Korea, and US$9843 across the FRCs. Throughout the 2010s, the figures were US$13542, US$38052, and US$48385, respectively. Relative to the FRCs, through the 1950s the Colombian income (38%) was more than three times that of Korea (12%). Seven decades later relative income increased to circa 80% for Korea and decreased below 30% for Colombia.

From , countries under the 45-degree diagonal have much larger relative income during the 2010s, than at the origin (1950s, 1960s, 1970s). The contrary happens for countries over the diagonal. Countries near the origin and/or close to the diagonal on either side reveal minor progress or even a slight decline in their relative income. Notice, for instance, that over the 1970s–2010s Suriname barely improved its income position, while for Taiwan the relative income in the 2010s is much larger and for Venezuela it is lower than at the origin. Even among FRCs, there are some countries that clearly improved their position with respect to the origin and others that failed to do so.

Figure 1. Relative levels of income per capita. The big grey circles are FRCs, the big white ones are the CUCs, the big black ones are the STCs and the small ones are the LGCs. Countries below the 45-degree line are better off in the last decade. The position of every country indicates their catching up performance – e.g., at the origin, the relative income of Hong Kong was about 60% off the frontier, in the 2010s it was well over 100%.

Figure 1. Relative levels of income per capita. The big grey circles are FRCs, the big white ones are the CUCs, the big black ones are the STCs and the small ones are the LGCs. Countries below the 45-degree line are better off in the last decade. The position of every country indicates their catching up performance – e.g., at the origin, the relative income of Hong Kong was about 60% off the frontier, in the 2010s it was well over 100%.

In fact, in the case of Suriname there is a slight decrease between the 1970s (30.7%) and the 2010s (30.2%). By taking the ratio between the latter and the former figures the conclusion is reached that no meaningful change occurred in the position of this country with respect to the frontier (30.7%/30.2% 1.0). A similar conclusion is reached for Paraguay (1.0), the Dominican Republic (1.2), India (1.1), Chile (0.95), Peru (0.92), and Morocco (1.1). In contrast, there is a group of countries that managed to improve their position: Korea (7.0), Taiwan (4.3), Thailand (3.0), Egypt (3.6), and Romania (2.9); and another group that fell farther apart over the decades: Mexico (0.65), Colombia (0.74), Congo (0.07).

Thus, let’s consider an ad-hoc 0.75–1.25 threshold. Countries for which the relative income ratio rises or falls by less than a quarter are classified as stagnant (STCs); countries that are above the upper-bound are classified as catching-up (CUCs); and countries that are below the lower-bound are classified as laggard (LGCs). Based on this criterion, the 131 countries in the sample split into 24 FRCs, 26 CUCs, 27 STCs, and 54 LGCs.Footnote6

As most classifications are, this is somewhat arbitrary. After all, a relative income ratio barely over 1 implies that a country would be able to catching-up even if in the far distant future. Similarly, a relative income ratio barely under 1 implies that countries are getting away of the frontier even if quite slowly over time. Furthermore, accounting only for changes between the latest decade and the origin may simply indicate that a country was doing well (or bad) in that particular decade. It tell us nothing of what happens in the decades in between.

To address the first of these concerns, one may apply different threshold widths. Clearly, a narrower width implies more countries in the extremes (the catching-up and laggard classifications). However, it seems unlikely that countries that are only slightly below (above) unity have performed permanently as bad (well) as those that are farther away. Also, while allowing more countries in the extremes does not appear to be innocuous, it definitively does not invalidate the diverse patterns of convergence/divergence that are argued here for the CUCs, STCs, and LGCs.

To address the second concern, using 10-year moving averages seems more appropriate. This leads to smooth trends that reflect the ability/failure of countries to achieve rates of economic growth consistent with catching-up. In , the long-run trends fit well with the proposed four-types of countries classification even after factoring out extreme country cases – which implies that time clusters reflect the performance of middle income and more stable countries.Footnote7

Figure 2. Relative levels of income per capita of CUCs (a), STCs (b), and LGCs (c). The upper solid-line is the frontier. The three thick dashed lines below the frontier are 10-year moving averages of relative income for clusters of countries over 1950s–2010s, 1960s–2010s, and 1970s–2010s. The thin dotted lines in (a) show represent the Asian Nics, the thin solid line the HInonOECDs. The dotted and solid lines in (b) and (c) represent the LICs and fragile countries, respectively.

Figure 2. Relative levels of income per capita of CUCs (a), STCs (b), and LGCs (c). The upper solid-line is the frontier. The three thick dashed lines below the frontier are 10-year moving averages of relative income for clusters of countries over 1950s–2010s, 1960s–2010s, and 1970s–2010s. The thin dotted lines in (a) show represent the Asian Nics, the thin solid line the HInonOECDs. The dotted and solid lines in (b) and (c) represent the LICs and fragile countries, respectively.

4. Growth gaps

Provided that backward countries grow faster than countries at the frontier, predicting the potential to catching-up amounts to calculate the average gap between these two growth rates.

gˉgap=gˉigˉFRCs|gˉi>>gˉFRCs

Clearly, the smaller the gap the larger the time needed to catching-up.Footnote8 The condition gˉi>>gˉFRCs implies that countries exhibiting negative growth gaps will not be able to catching-up at all.

In , growth gaps are calculated yearly and depicted as 10-year moving averages over relevant country classifications and time clusters. Again, extreme country cases are plotted apart. Despite cyclical fluctuations, the growth gaps in panel (a) are generally positive, consistent with the fact that the CUCs have grown permanently faster than countries at the frontier regardless the excepcional performance atributed to Asian Nics and other HInonOECDs.

Figure 3. Growth gaps CUCs (a), STCs (b) and LGCs (c). The zero line is the frontier. The other three thick lines are time clusters over 1950s–2010s, 1960s–2010s, and 1970s–2010s. Thin dotted and dashed lines in (a) are the Nics and HInonOECDs, in (b) are the LICs and fragile states.

Figure 3. Growth gaps CUCs (a), STCs (b) and LGCs (c). The zero line is the frontier. The other three thick lines are time clusters over 1950s–2010s, 1960s–2010s, and 1970s–2010s. Thin dotted and dashed lines in (a) are the Nics and HInonOECDs, in (b) are the LICs and fragile states.

By contrast, in panel (b) growth gaps for the STCs fluctuate around the zero-cutoff. The sequencial periods of faster and slower growth of these countries with respect to the frontier offer a possible explanation why these countries have failed to close their income gaps. Finally, in panel (c), growth gaps for the LGCs are generally below the zero-cutoff which is the likely reason why these countries have been diverging from the frontier over time.

Notice, however, the increasing trends in the data for the STCs and LGCs after the 1990s. The tendency shown by the countries in these groups to close their growth gaps with the frontier is what gave a cause for optimism to researchers that have taken it as an indication of a new path of unconditional convergence in the world economy (Patel et al., Citation2021; Roy et al., Citation2016). Unfortunately after the 2000s, the evidence appears less clear cut. Apparently, the well-known crisis at the end of the latter decade affected all countries, and was particularly adverse to LGCs.

5. Distance to the frontier

Combining both, relative income and growth gaps, allows for some interesting predictions about the time that it would take backward countries to reach the frontier. For instance, a country with relative income of 10% and a growth gap of +1 pp would reach the frontier in around 230 years; using the same growth gap, a country with relative income of 50% would reach the frontier in 70 years; and with a growth gap of +5 pp the first country would reach the frontier in less than 50 years.

This is a simple application of the “Rule of 70”. Consider a country i with average income yˉi which grows steadily at the rate gˉi. The time that it would take to catching-up with the frontier’s income yˉFRCs which grows at the rate gˉFRCs, is given by the solution to the following problem

yˉiegˉiN=yˉFRCsegˉFRCsN

Taking natural logs on both sides and solving for N, the following conditions are obtained

(1) N=LN(yˉi/FRCs)(gˉigˉFRCs)1|gˉFRCs<gˉi(1)
(2) N=|gˉFRCsgˉi(2)

where yˉi/F is relative income and gˉigˉF is the growth gap. EquationEquation (1) indicates the time to catching-up when the growth gap is positive. EquationEquation (2) shows that no catching-up is possible when a country grows at a rate that is equal or less than the frontier’s.

plots this relationship for the 131 countries in the sample taking the average of relative income over the 2010s and the average growth rate for every country over the whole sample period. Panel (a) plots a fixed target scenario, assuming gˉFRCs = 0%. Panel (b) plots the actual target scenario, using gˉFRCs = 2.74%.

Figure 4. Time-distance to catching-up. FRCs (white), CUCs (grey), STCs (black bordered grey) and LGCs (black). Panel (a) assumes gˉFRCs=0%. Panel (b) uses gˉFRCs=2.74%, the average across frontier countries. Other horizontal lines depict the maximum and minimum growth in countries at the frontier.

Figure 4. Time-distance to catching-up. FRCs (white), CUCs (grey), STCs (black bordered grey) and LGCs (black). Panel (a) assumes gˉFRCs=0%. Panel (b) uses gˉFRCs=2.74%, the average across frontier countries. Other horizontal lines depict the maximum and minimum growth in countries at the frontier.

The fixed target scenario shows the FRCs grouped around the average (2.74%) at zero years to catching-up. The CUCs, the STCs and many LGCs are over the zero-pp line – and even over the minimum growth rate at the frontier. This implies, obviously, that when the frontier is a fixed target almost all countries have some probability to catching-up.

However, even under this optimistic scenario, a large number of LGCs would fail to reach the frontier at any time.Footnote9 In particular, under the fixed target scenario the CUCs would need on average 27 years to catching-up. Some countries (Singapore, Macao, Taiwan, Hong Kong, South Korea) are near fulfillment or already fulfilled the process, while others are farther away (Cape Verde, Cyprus). By comparison, the STCs would need on average 69 years, and the LGCs 246 years. But there are many countries with negative growth gaps that, consequently, will never even hope to catching-up. Excluding them, the LGCs would need 483 years.

The actual target scenario, panel (b), shows the FRCs grouped around the zero pp line. Now, only the CUCs show positive growth gaps. In turn, only three STCs (Bulgaria, the Dominican Republic, and India), and no LGCs show catching-up probabilities. In this scenario, the CUCs are, on average, at a distance of 194 years to the frontier. But there are large disparities in the predictions for individual countries: there are again the countries that are near or already fulfilled the process (Taiwan, South Korea, Singapore). But, there are others falling farther apart of the limit of 300 years: Albania (1374 years), Cape Verde (831), Tunisia (522), Argentine (470), and Myanmar (380). Among the STCs, Bulgaria shows the smallest distance to the frontier (234 years), while the Dominican Republic (619) and India (2242) are far apart.

Notice that time-distance to the frontier depends on the level of income considered the appropriate measure of richness. In , the reference income of the FRCs was US$48385 (PPP adjusted real GDP at 2017US$). This might be too high a standard for many countries. The minimum level of income and the lowest growth rate across FRCs are US$24437 and 1.8%. Using these measures, the average distance to the frontier is 20 years for the CUCs and 370 years for the STCs (excluding countries that would never make the catching-up). But even in this type of straightforward scenario only four countries in the LGCs show catching-up probabilities: Ethiopia (296), Mexico (287), Colombia (267) and Costa Rica (74).Footnote10

Summing up, the time-distance analysis shows than only the CUCs have been or may be able to fulfilled the catching-up process in feasible times. The weakness of the STCs to generate growth rates that are consistently above the frontier’s average, and the even worse growth performance of the LGCs, show why these countries remain stagnant or diverging farther away. Interestingly, the latter group includes several of the best examples of countries with a reasonable record of economic performance in other well-known classifications (see Spence, Citation2011).

6. Conventional convergence revisited

In this section, I run conventional β-convergence OLS-pooled regressions for countries within the FRCs classification and countries in each couple FRCs-CUCs, FRCs-STCs, and FRCs-LGCs with and without controlling for extreme country cases. As long as there are no further conditions, this may be consider an analysis of “unconditional convergence”.Footnote11

In , the negatively sloped relationship between the rate of growth and the level of income for the FRCs highlights the well-known convergence pattern documented elsewhere for advanced countries. There are also negatively sloped and steep trends for the couple FRCs-CUCs, and much flatter trends for the FRCs-STCs, whereas for the FRCs-LGCs the data suggest positively sloped trends instead. In other words, the evidence suggests a pattern of convergence between the CUCs and the FRCs but not between the STCs and FRCs, and suggests a process of divergence between the LGCs and the FRCs.

Figure 5. Relative income per-capita in the 1970s and growth gaps over 1970s-2010s. The thicker black line and grey circles are the FRCs. The dotted lines on the top and white circles are the CUCs before (black line) and after subtracting the Nics and HInOECDs (grey line). The dashed lines in the middle correspond to the STCs before (black line) and after subtracting LICs, HInOECDs, and Frags (grey line). The bottom-most dash-dotted lines correspond to the LGCs before and after subtracting LICs and Frags.

Figure 5. Relative income per-capita in the 1970s and growth gaps over 1970s-2010s. The thicker black line and grey circles are the FRCs. The dotted lines on the top and white circles are the CUCs before (black line) and after subtracting the Nics and HInOECDs (grey line). The dashed lines in the middle correspond to the STCs before (black line) and after subtracting LICs, HInOECDs, and Frags (grey line). The bottom-most dash-dotted lines correspond to the LGCs before and after subtracting LICs and Frags.

Table 1. Estimates of β-convergence. The regressions are based on OLS-pooled regressions, the dependent variable is the growth gap over 1970s–2010s. The explanatory variable is relative income per capita in the 1970s. Decade dummies are included over 1980s-2010s. X-1 and X-2 denote regressions before and after controlling for the Nics, HInOECDs, LICs, and Frags. Sandwich-robust standard errors reported in parentheses. The half-life of adjustment denotes the years needed to eliminate a half of the income gap with the frontier, HLA= 12niln(yi/yFRCs)/(β Xs). This is 115 years for the CUCs and 518 for the STCs. The positive β Xs of the LGCs implies that the HLA goes to infinity.

The β-convergence estimates in are obtained from the following regression

gˉi,τ=α+βyˉi/FRCs,1970s+Dτ+DZτ+ετ

the dependent variable is the growth gap for the country over 1970s-2010s (5 observations per country), yˉi/FRCs,1970s is the relative income per capita between a country and the frontier in the 1970s. Dτ denotes decade specific dummies and DZ denote dummies to control for extreme country cases.

As expected, coefficient estimates suggest a significant convergence effect for the CUCs. The coefficient for the CUCs-1 (−0.008) is statistically significant and robust after controlling for the Nics and HInOECDs. In the case of the STCs, the convergence effect is not statistically significant. In the case of the LGCs-1, the positive sign of the coefficient suggests a statistically significant pattern of divergence. But this result is not robust, as may be seen for the regression of the LGCs-2.

The so-called half-life of adjustment reveals patterns that are roughly consistent with the findings in the previous section. On average, it would take around 115 years for the CUCs and 518 years for the STCs to eliminate half of their initial income gap with the FRCs, while for the LGCs the evidence suggests no convergence possibilities.

Interestingly, the data suggests also the possibility of σ-convergence within every group of countries other than the LGCs. In particular, using the coefficient of variation (CV) to normalize the dispersion, over 1970s-2010s the data suggests a decline for the FRCs from (0.11 to 0.07), the CUCs (from 0.31 to 0.21) and the STCs (from 0.28 to 0.22). By contrast, for the LGCs the dispersion increases steadily from 0.27 to 0.42 in the 1990s and remained stable till 2010s.Footnote12

It remains to be seen whether countries off the frontier are able to rectify the relatively large periods of time needed to catching-up that are suggested by the above calculations. Among a much larger list of feasible explanations, too large to be discussed here, the extensive literature relating to the causes and consequences of underdevelopment with a focus on cross-country settings has questioned whether convergence hinges on the virtues of accumulation (Mankiw et al., Citation1995; Young, Citation1995), technological diffusion and the ability of countries to use the received technology/replicate the conditions that allowed the technologies developed at the frontier (Baldwin et al., Citation2001; Clark & Feenstra, Citation2003; Easterly & Levine, Citation2000; Lin & Monga, Citation2011; Mankiw et al., Citation1995; Rodrik, Citation2011; Romer, Citation1993; Sachs & Warner, Citation1995), or on their ability to assimilate and innovate (Nelson & Pack, Citation1999; Perilla, Citation2019, Citation2020; Wade, Citation1996). An analysis of these issues is presented in the next section.

7. Cross-country differences in technology

A relative consensus in growth economics is that cross-country income differences are closely related to differences in productivity which, in turn, are associated with differences in technology.Footnote13

Below, I show that while income differences appear to mirror productivity differences across countries, the decomposition of productivity into local efficiency – a measure or indication of the impact of innovation – and technical change – a measure of the impact of technology diffusion/adoption – suggests that catching-up strongly depends on innovation.

7.1. Productivity performance and catching-up

Following Caselli (Citation2005), I use development accounting techniques to assessing to what extent differences in income (per worker) are explained by productivity differences across countries. The question to answer is how much of the differences in relative income between a country and the frontier is explained by differences in the endowment of productive factors and, by subtraction, how much by differences in productivity.

Consider the standard production function in per-worker terms of country i at time t relative to the frontier,

(3) y˜i=yi/yˉFRCs=AiAˉFRCskikˉFRCsαhihˉFRCs1α=A˜iq˜i(3)

where xi,xˉFRCs are yearly figures and the latter denotes the average at the frontier (time subscripts dropped for simplicity). k is the capital stock and h is the “quality adjusted” workforce (the number of workers times their average human capital). The capital-share, α=1/3 is assumed to be country and time invariant.Footnote14

the log-variance decomposition of the above equation is

var(lny˜)=var(lnA˜)+var(lnq˜)+2cov(lnA˜,lnq˜)

if there are no productivity differences across countries, the second and fourth term of the last equation are both equal to zero. In such a situation, the factors-only share of the difference in income per worker is

Zkh=var(lnq˜)var(lny˜)

thus, the productivity share of income differences is given by

(4) ZA=1var(lnq˜)var(lny˜)(4)

To emphasize the distance to the frontier, the variances in the last expression are calculated with respect to the average at the frontier

var(xiX)=1NiN(xiXxˉFRCs)2

where X{FRCs,CUCs,STCs,LGCs}. Thus, the factors-only share for each country classification are calculated in the following way

Zkh,tX=var(lnq˜tX)var(lny˜tX)

Clearly, Zkh,tX=1 when income differences are fully explained by differences in factor endowments. Otherwise, 1-Zkh,tX gives an indication of the share of income difference that are explained by productivity. I apply this decomposition to a sample of 110 countries with complete information on relevant variables over 1970–2019 (24 FRCs, 21 CUCs, 25 STCs, 40 LGCs).Footnote15 From , panel (a), the median of the distribution across all countries is 0.37 (std = 0.08, min = 0.30, max = 0.53) which is wholly consistent with results found in other studies that usually focus on either a single year or shorter time periods, using different versions of the data and different country samples (Caselli, Citation2005; King & Levine, Citation1994).

Figure 6. Dispersion of the factors-only share and productivity conditional on the average at the frontier. The thick grey line depicts all countries, the thick black line the FRCs, the dashed line the CUCs, the dotted line the STCs, and the thin line the LGCs. Panel (a) shows the distribution based on a sample of 110 countries over 1970–2019 (24 FRCs, 21 CUCs, 25 STCs, 40 LGCs), panels (b) and (c) are based on an adjusted sample of 59 countries (20 FRCs, 11 CUCs, 12 STCs, 16 LGCs, excluding extreme country cases and adjusting the distribution at the frontier to remain between the 10th-90th percentiles). Panel (c) shows productivity share differences.

Figure 6. Dispersion of the factors-only share and productivity conditional on the average at the frontier. The thick grey line depicts all countries, the thick black line the FRCs, the dashed line the CUCs, the dotted line the STCs, and the thin line the LGCs. Panel (a) shows the distribution based on a sample of 110 countries over 1970–2019 (24 FRCs, 21 CUCs, 25 STCs, 40 LGCs), panels (b) and (c) are based on an adjusted sample of 59 countries (20 FRCs, 11 CUCs, 12 STCs, 16 LGCs, excluding extreme country cases and adjusting the distribution at the frontier to remain between the 10th-90th percentiles). Panel (c) shows productivity share differences.

Surprisingly, as one would expect productivity to play a more powerful and systematic influence in income differences at the frontier, in panel (a) the median and variability of the factors-only share is much larger for the FRCs (median = 0.71, std = 0.24) than for other country classifications: the LGCs (median = 0.34, std = 0.09), the CUCs (median = 0.42, std = 0.08), and the STCs (median = 0.46, std = 0.06). However, the data suggests a consistent pattern of income per capita differences that are explained largely by differences in productivity.

The sensitivity of development accounting to extreme values has led some researchers to consider alternative scenarios, e.g., the 90th–10th percentile ratio of the distribution of the factors-only share (Caselli, Citation2005). I follow that procedure for the FRCs but consider a different approach for other country groups taking into account the wide diversity in the performance of relevant economic variables across low-income countries (LIC), fragile democracies (Frags) and high-income countries that are not part of the OECD (HInOECDs) as well as the NICs. Basically, by excluding those extreme country cases, a more stable sample is obtained that is better suited for the analysis, including a rather compact distribution at the frontier and middle-income countries that have enjoyed good economic performance over long periods of time. The new sample accounts for 59 countries (20 FRCs, 11 CUCs, 12 STCs, 16 LGCs).

From panel (b), the new sample leads to a significant reduction in the overall distribution of the factors-only share (median = 0.34, std = 0.08). The most meaningful reduction occurs at the frontier (median = 0.25, std = 0.05), followed by the CUCs (median = 0.34, std = 0.08), the STCs (median = 0.36, std = 0.09), and only a minor reduction in the LGCs (median = 0.33, std = 0.09).

Remarkably, the ability of the factors-only share to explain income differences has been reducing over time (e.g., for the FRCs it goes from 0.39 in 1970 to 0.10 in 2019), thereby indicating that productivity has become increasingly more important over time as the fundamental explanation of differences in income between backward countries and the frontier.

Using EquationEquation (4), panel (c) shows that productivity differences explain between 61% (1970) and 90% (2019) of the differences in income across the FRCs (median = 75%), and they have a relatively larger influence on the CUCs and LGCs differences with respect to FRCs (the LGCs slightly to the right) than the STCs. In particular, in terms of productivity the CUCs, 59% <ZACUCs<79% (median = 66%), and the LGCs, 45% <ZALGCs< 74% (median = 67%) were moving faster in the direction of the frontier than the STCs, 43%<ZASTCs< 73% (median = 64%). Z-test statistics support the null hypothesis that the STCs are significantly behind the FRCs and the CUCs. But not from the LGCs. Also, the CUCs and LGCs are significantly distributed to the left of the FRCs, and the LGCs are significantly to the right of the CUCs.Footnote16

Summing up, despite overlaps, income differences with the frontier appear dominated by the substantial contribution of productivity differences over the 1970–2019. But still the STCs appear to have been relatively more affected by their failure to accumulate productive factors than the LGCs and the CUCs, which in turn appear to have been mostly affected by productivity weaknesses. The preeminence of productivity is consistent with earlier findings in the development accounting tradition (Caselli, Citation2005; King & Levine, Citation1994), the distinct results found for the country classifications above suggest that the exclusive focus on productivity is insufficient to gain perspective on the apparently complex interactions that are important to understand the ability of backward countries to catching-up.

7.2. Diffusion or innovation, which matters the most?

Productivity decomposition has become instrumental to break down total factor productivity into technical changes–indicating shifts in the technology frontier – and efficiency changes–indicating the distance of a particular economy to the frontier (Fare et al., Citation1994; Farrell, Citation1957; Kumar & Russell, Citation2002; Los & Timmer, Citation2005). Below, this approach is used to identify the influence of technology diffusion and local innovation on the ability of countries to catching-up.

In particular, it seems acceptable to view technology diffusion from abroad as inexorably related to the concept of “technical change” which is essentially associated to new inventions/ideas that spread worldwide. In turn, “efficiency changes” may be reasonably associated to technology adoption and indigenous innovation to the extent that it reflects the ability to put the received inventions/ideas to commercial purpose through new products and production processes. In fact, a large consensus in growth economics appears to subscribe now to the view that technical changes are exogenously determined by the most productive countries in the world, while “efficiency” depends basically on local efforts (Benhabib et al., Citation2014; Coe & Helpman, Citation1995; Gault, Citation2023; Keller, Citation2002, Citation2004; Kumar & Russell, Citation2002).Footnote17

From a methodological point of view, “technical changes” are calculated with reference to countries able to produce more output out of a given set of inputs. One shortcoming of this approach is that resource abundant economies or countries enjoying some sort of advantage of backwardness may become part of the frontier even if they are not regarded the actual technology leaders. As there is no obvious solution to this problem in the literature, results referring to the “technical change” should be taken with caution to the extent that they do not necessarily take the FRCs as the benchmark.Footnote18

Let the non-parametric Farrell (output based) efficiency problem for country i at time t be defined in the following way

E(y˜i,k˜i,h˜i)=max{θ|(θy˜i,k˜i,h˜i)τCRS}

Where y˜,k˜,h˜ are the measures of relative income and production factors defined in EquationEquation (3), 1θ< is an expansion factor and θ1 represents the maximal increase in output that is feasible given the actual amounts of factor inputs and technology τ in the reference period.

The Farrell efficiency index is the result of solving the following linear program for each country i

Maxθ,λθ:θy˜i,x˜iτ,x˜i=(k˜i,h˜i)
s.t.θy˜iiλiy˜i;x˜iiλix˜i;θ,λi0;i=1,2,N

Note that 01/θ1 represents the technical efficiency score of this problem. θ=1 implies that the country is part of the technological frontier under a constant returns to scale level of operation. The Variable Returns to Scale (VRS) technology requires the additional restriction iλi1. The ratio between the CRS and the VRS score reflects scale efficiency (Coelli et al., Citation2005).

SE=τCRSτVRS

Where

τX=(y˜i,x˜i)R+3|y˜iiλiy˜i,x˜iiλix˜i,λiX0

for X=(CRS, VRS).

By construction, the CRS efficiency index may be obtained by multiplying scale efficiency and the VRS efficiency index,

τCRS=SE×τVRS

In multi-time periods efficiency measures may be obtained using the Malmquist index approach using chained indices based on the linear program introduced above. In this case, a decomposition is possible of TFP into technical changes, scale efficiency changes, and local innovation changes (Coelli et al., Citation2005; Malmquist, Citation1953).Footnote19

illustrates this approach in the two-dimensional space for one output (Y) and one input (X) over two periods – X(0) and X(1). This seems adequate to illustrate the differences between VRS and CRS.

Figure 7. Productivity decomposition.

Figure 7. Productivity decomposition.

Under VRS, the technical change component – shifts in the frontier associated to technology diffusion/adoption – is measured by the ratio Yf/Yd when the technology is X(1), and the ratio Yc/Yb when the technology is X(0). The Malmquist index approach is based on the geometric mean of these two measures

Δtech|VRS=YfYd×YcYb1/2

Under CRS the index is

Δtech|CRS=Yf Yd ×Yc Yb 1/2

Likewise, the scale efficiency change – the distance between the CRS and VRS frontiers – is measured by the ratio Yd /Yd×Yf /Yf when the technology is X(1), and Yb /Yb×Yc /Yc when the technology is X(0). The geometric mean of these quantities is

(5) Δseff=Δtech|CRSΔtech|VRS=Yf /Yc Yf/Yc×Yd /Yb Yd/Yb1/2=1,CRS<1,IRS,DRS(5)

where Yf/Yc and Yd/Yb capture de productivity effect of factor increases (therefore the adoption of new technology) between X(0) and X(1) along the VRS-based frontier and Yf /Yc  and Yd /Yb  do it along the CRS-based frontier.

Notice that when Δtech|VRS = Δtech|CRS production takes place at the technically optimal productive scale under a CRS technology, therefore, the scale efficiency is equal to unity. Otherwise, the economy exhibits scale inefficiencies due to increasing or decreasing returns to scale.

Lastly, the distance of the economy to the VRS-based frontier is measured by the ratio Ye/YfYa/Yb. This captures the ability of the economy to short the distance to the frontier after accounting for technical changes (shifts in the frontier) and scale (in)efficiencies. Thus, it is a measure of local innovative efficiency,

Δinneff=Ye/YfYa/Yb

Total factor productivity changes are obtained by multiplying the above three components:

Δtfp=Δtech×Δseff×Δinneff

For comparison purposes, following Inklaar and Timmer (Citation2013), a conventional growth accounting parametric estimate of TFP is based on the following representation.

ctfpi=A˜i=y˜i/q˜i

where A˜,y˜,q˜ are defined in EquationEquation (3), and the relevant capital share is assumed to be country and time invariant (α=1/3).Footnote20

shows decade-averages of the parametric and non-parametric measures of productivity and relevant decompositions. The estimates are based on yearly calculations of the linear program for the sample of 110 countries with complete information over 1970–2019 (left panel), and the sample of 59 countries after exclusion of extreme country cases and the 10th-90th percentiles adjustment of the FRCs (right panel).

Table 2. Decade-averages of cross-country TFP changes and their components (for the FRCs (1970s): Δtfp=(10.0848)×(10.0114)×(1+0.0969)=(0.9921)). Results obtained from the software DEAP (Coelli et al., Citation2005.).

Obviously, the non-parametric (Δtfp) and conventional (Δctfp) estimates of productivity are different in magnitude. However, despite the methodological differences, these measures display roughly procyclical patterns which support the relevance of the non-parametric approach to capture the essencial features of productivity for the sample of countries in this research. The Pearson’s correlation coefficient between both productivity approaches is quite high in all cases (generally over 0.9). Particularly, after excluding extreme country cases. The exception is the CUCs when the whole sample is used (correlation coefficient of 0.83).

There are three issues worth highlighting from the results in

  1. The CUCs are the only countries that appear to have been unaffected by the widespread productivity slowdown of the 1970s, and appear to have been more successful to cope with the decline that followed through the 1980s and 1990s which, on the contrary, was particularly severe for STCs and LGCs. As a result, despite some underperformance in later decades, the CUCs exhibit more favourable productivity records than the STCs and LGCs when the focus is on the overall mean of the nonparametric measure of productivity, Δtfp (−0.54 on the left and −0.46 on the right panel).Footnote21

  2. The CUC’s success is explained by a stronger combination of innovation and scale efficiency compared to other backward countries. This group exhibits the highest Δineff overall mean rates even after the exclusion of extreme country cases (1.21 on the left and 0.39 on the right hand panel), and also the highest rates of Δseff (only surpassed by the FRCs in the panel on the left).

  3. With focus on the overall mean, technical change (Δtech|VRS) was decreasing in general for all groups of countries and in both panels. However, by excluding extreme country cases, the superior performance of the FRCs seems apparent in all decades but the 1980s. This seems consistent with well-established stylized facts according to which the pattern of worldwide technical change is led by a few countries at the frontier which account for most of the international creation of new technology (Keller, Citation2002, Citation2004).

It seems evident, from the above analysis, that the average growth of productivity across the four-types of countries does not support the expectations of “unconditional convergence” discussed earlier in this paper. The evidence in the table seems more accurately described as complex fluctuations around long-run trends that are clearly determined and consistent with the patterns of catching-up, stagnation and laggardness defined above and well supported by empirical evidence emerging from cross country comparisons. In particular, the good performance of the CUCs relative to the FRCs is in sharp contrast with the poor performance of the STCs and LGCs, and the latter’s is much more dissapointing despite the evident improvement in the 2010s.

Notice also, from the results in the table, that substantial productivity benefits (from the Δtfp perspective) accrue through the effective combination of innovation efficiency (Δineff) and scale efficiency (Δseff). In fact, leaving aside the negative contribution of technical change, it seems apparent that productivity differences between the CUCs and other country groups, including the FRCs, are well explained by differences in the magnitude and correspondence between changes in innovation and scale efficiency.

Firstly, as mentioned before, the high rate of innovation combined with increasing scale efficiency shows up as the most salient fact in the CUCs performance whether one focus on the more heterogeneous group of countries in the left hand panel or the more stable middle-income economies in the right hand panel. Secondly, in contrast with the CUCs and FRCs, the STCs and LGCs major weaknesses are associated with a much lower increase in both components, and even a decline in scale efficiency (in the case of the LGCs). These two aspects are very important to understand the convergence probabilities of these countries in the distant future.

Remarkably, over the 2010s, the LGCs appear to perform so much better than any other group in productivity, and this can be explained by a large increase in innovation efficiency whether one focus on the right of the left hand side panel. This behavior is consistent with the distribution of the LGCs to the right of other groups but the FRCs in panel (c), and provides support to the convergence optimism of some researchers as was discussed in a previous section. But, clearly, it seems too early to derive the likely implications of this performance over the long-run.

Summing up, the productivity outcomes discussed above give support to the four-types of countries classification introduced in this paper, and provide suggestive evidence that catching-up hinges critically on the factors determining local innovation along the diffusion/adoption of technology from abroad.

8. Concluding remarks

I have tried to build a picture of the world economy upon the observation that, contrary to the optimistic claim in recent research that foresees a path of unconditional convergence, over long periods of time only a few countries have been successfully catching-up, whereas many other remain stagnant or keep lagging behind. Catching-up is a dynamic phenomenon that hinges upon the performance of both backward and leading countries. Thus, relative levels of income and adjusted growth rates are needed to say something about the speed and progress of the convergence process.

Using that approach, I have shown above that countries that exhibit consistent patterns of catching-up are at a distance of at least 27 years to reach the frontier in the most optimistic scenario. But they are to as much as 194 years if the frontier keeps growing at the historical pace. In turn, STCs countries are between 69 and more than two thousand years (India 2242 years) and LGCs between 483 but only when countries with negative growth rates are excluded.

Productivity decompositions provide another piece of suggesting evidence supporting the view that successful catching-up accrues through the effective combination of domestic innovation efficiency alongside the adoption of technology from abroad. This outcome is consistent with conclusions from recent research on the complex feedback effects that exist between technology diffusion/adoption and indigenous innovation in recipient countries. The policy implications for the design and implementation of macroeconomic policy highlight the importance of innovation incentives as the driving force of economic growth and catching-up (Malerba & Lee, Citation2020; Nelson & Pack, Citation1999; Perilla, Citation2019, Citation2020).

A worthwhile avenue for future research under this framework would be to investigate the fundamental determinants and cross-country differences in the approach to innovation policy, and the likely macroeconomic and environmental implications of getting all countries in the four-types framework to reach the income standards of the countries at the frontier.

Supplemental material

Supplemental Material

Download PDF (88.3 KB)

Acknowledgments

The author greatly acknowledges comments received from the editor of this journal and two anonymous referees on a previous version of the paper. This research has also benefited from the comments and extensive discussion with Thomas Ziesemer and Bart Verspagen at Maastricht University and the United Nations University – Maastricht Economic and Social Research Institute on Innovation and Technology, UNU-MERIT. Usual Disclaimers apply.

Disclosure statement

No potential conflict of interest was reported by the author.

Supplemental material

Supplemental data for this article can be accessed online at https://doi.org/10.1080/15140326.2024.2339701

Correction Statement

This article has been corrected with minor changes. These changes do not impact the academic content of the article.

Additional information

Funding

The work was supported by the Universiteit Maastricht.

Notes

1 See https://www.rug.nl/ggdc/productivity/pwt. S. Johnson et al. (Citation2013) show that specific results vary using alternative datasets. Patel et al. (Citation2021), indicate that while PWT tends to favour divergence in earlier decades it does not invalidate convergence patterns in most recent data.

2 I use PWT V.10.0 output-side real GDP at chained PPPs (in mil. 2017US$)–rgdpo). Rich oil-producing countries, non-OECD high-income countries with relative income per-capita larger than 75% of the frontier at the origin, and countries with data over less than two decades, are excluded.

3 I consider i) a cluster of 35 countries with data over the 1950s-2010s; ii) a cluster of 49 countries with data over 1960s-2010s; and iii) a cluster of 23 countries with data over 1970s-2010s.

4 Decade averages are calculated as long as there is data for at least 8 years.

5 https://www.oecd.org. Using this benchmark rather than a single country (like the U.S.) has the advantage that the OECD represents a wider variety of capitalism and institutional practices (See Hall & Soskice, Citation2004).

6 See the Appendix.

7 Most Low Income Countries (LICs) and many countries characterized as having weak institutions and poor governance, so-called fragile states (Frags), classify as LGCs. Likewise, all of the so-called New Industrialized Asian Economies-NICs (Hong Kong, Singapore, Taiwan, South Korea), and most of the High Income Countries that are not part of the OECD (HInOECDs) classify as CUCS. To prevent a misleading influence on long-run trajectories, in these specific country cases are depicted apart.

8 A gap of 1 pp for a country that has half the FRC’s income indicates that catch-up will take 70 years; but with a gap of 0.1 pp it will take 700 years.

9 Countries as Burundi or Algeria would need more that 300 years to catching-up. But Central African Republic, Djibouti, and Congo would not be able to catching-up at all. As a rule of thumb, countries falling behind far beyond 300 years are plotted at −300 (these countries are even behind the starting gate of modern economic growth initiated with the onset of the industrial revolution – see Lucas, Citation2000).

10 Interestingly, the distance to the frontier, and indeed the decline in relative income of the three Latin American countries in the latter group between the 1950s and the 2010s (Colombia from 38% to 28%, Costa Rica from 46% to 33%, and Mexico from 59% to 38%) is in strong contrast with the optimism on their economic performance in other country classifications. For instance, these countries belong to the World Bank UMICs: Mexico since 1990, Costa Rica since 2000, and Colombia since 2008, and all of them are among the latest members of the OECDs: Mexico 1994, Colombia 2020, and Costa Rica 2021).

11 Alternatively, a “conditional convergence” test can be run based on the fact that countries belong to distinct convergence clubs.

12 Calculations are available from the author.

13 See Dougherty and Jorgenson (Citation1996), and Jorgenson and Vu (Citation2005) for counter arguments.

14 α=1/3 is a standard value in growth literature. Alternatively, one may use country specific and time varying statistics on factors shares. However, Gollin (Citation2002), and Pritchett (Citation2000a), provide solid arguments to be cautious on the reliability of official statistics in this regard.

15 I use the following data from PWT V.10.0: Output-side real GDP (cgdpo) and capital stock (cn) at current PPPs in millions of 2017US$, number of persons engaged (emp) and the human capital index (h). The smaller sample size is because some countries in the original sample of 131 countries lack the data on factor inputs that is needed in this section.

16 The Z-mean test is runned for every pair of country classifications, e.g., for the FRCs and STCs, the null hypothesis is.

Ho:μFRCsμSTCs=0

which is distributed at the 99% as follows:

(μ,σ2,N)FRCs=(0.76,0.01,50)and(μ,σ2,N)STCs=(0.64,0.01,50)

Thus, (0.76,0.01,50)FRCs-(0.64,0.01,50)STCs = −6.55 (P <|z| = 2.92E–11).

17 Fare et al. (Citation1994) associate changes in efficiency to catching-up and technical changes to innovation instead. The different use of the terms is because they think of “innovation” as technology produced at the frontier, and “catching-up” as local efforts to reach the frontier.

18 I have forced the model to use only FRCs as the benchmark. But this approach leads to minor variation in the results.

19 In this case, the linear program must be calculated for each country and time period, e.g., if there are N countries and T time periods a total of N×(3T–2) programs need to be calculated.

20 In spite that PWT V.10 report statistics for ctfp using USA as the benchmark and country specific factor shares, I rely on the average across FRCs as the benchmark and constant factor shares.

21 Notice that when the focus is on the overall mean of the conventional measure of productivity, Δctfp, the CUCs are even more successful than the FRCs.

Unknown widget #5d0ef076-e0a7-421c-8315-2b007028953f

of type scholix-links

References

  • Abramovitz, M. (1986). Catching up, forging ahead, and falling behind. The Journal of Economic History, 46(2), 385–24. https://doi.org/10.1017/S0022050700046209
  • Ayerst, S., Ibrahim, F., MacKenzie, G., & Rachapalli, S. (2023). Trade and diffusion of embodied technology: An empirical analysis. Journal of Monetary Economics, 137, 128–145. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jmoneco.2023.05.002
  • Baldwin, R., Martin, P., & Ottaviano, G. (2001, March). Global income divergence, trade, and industrialisation: The geography of growth take-offs. Journal of Economic Growth, 6(1), 5–37. https://doi.org/10.1023/A:1009876310544
  • Barro, R. (2015). Convergence and modernization. Economic Journal, 125(585), 911–942. https://doi.org/10.1111/ecoj.12247
  • Barro, R., & Sala-I-Martin, X. (1997, March). Technological diffusion and convergence. Journal of Economic Growth, 2(1), 1–26. https://doi.org/10.1023/A:1009746629269
  • Baumol, W. (1986). Productivity growth, convergence, and welfare: What the long-run data show. The American Economic Review, 76(5), 1072–1085.
  • Benhabib, J., Perla, J., & Tonetti, C. (2014). Catch-up and fall-back through innovation and imitation. Journal of Economic Growth, 19(1), 1–35. https://doi.org/10.1007/s10887-013-9095-z
  • Cai, J., Li, N., & Santacreu, A. (2022). Knowledge diffusion, trade, and innovation across countries and sectors. American Economic Journal Macroeconomics, 14(1), 104–145. https://doi.org/10.1257/mac.20200084
  • Caselli, F. (2005). The missing input, accounting for cross-country income differences. In P. Aghion & S. Durlauf (Eds.), Handbook of Economic Growth, Bd (Vol. 9, pp. 679–741). Amsterdam: Elsevier.
  • Chen, S., & Ravallion, M. (2010). The developing world is poorer than we thought, but no less successful in the fight against poverty. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 125(4), 1577–1625. https://doi.org/10.1162/qjec.2010.125.4.1577
  • Clark, G., & Feenstra, R. (2003). Technology in the great divergence ( pp. 277–322). National Bureau of Economic Research.
  • Coe, D., & Helpman, E. (1995). International R&D spillovers. European Economic Review, 39(5), 859–887. https://doi.org/10.1016/0014-2921(94)00100-E
  • Coelli, T., Rao, D., O’Donnell, C., & Battese, G. (2005). An introduction to efficiency and productivity analysis. Springer Science and Business Media.
  • Comin, D., & Hobijn, B. (2010). An exploration of technology diffusion. American Economic Review, 100(5), 2031–2059. https://doi.org/10.1257/aer.100.5.2031
  • Comin, D., & Nanda, R. (2019). Financial development and technology diffusion. IMF Economic Review, 67(2), 395–419. https://doi.org/10.1057/s41308-019-00078-0
  • Dougherty, C., & Jorgenson, J. (1996). International comparison of sources of growth. American Economic Review, 86(2), 25–29.
  • Easterly, W., & Levine, R. (2000). What have we learned from a decade of empirical research on growth? It’s not factor accumulation: Stylized facts and growth models. The World Bank Economic Review, 15, 177–219. https://doi.org/10.1093/wber/15.2.177 2
  • Elmslie, B. (1995). Retrospectives: The convergence debate between David Hume and Josiah Tucker. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 9(4), 207–216. https://doi.org/10.1257/jep.9.4.207
  • Fagerberg, J. (1995). Convergence or Divergence? The impact of technology on why growth rates differ. Journal of Evolutionary Economics, 5(3), 269–284. Spring. https://doi.org/10.1007/BF01198307
  • Fagerberg, J., Srholec, M., & Verspagen, B. (2010). Innovation and economic development. In B. Hall & N. Rosenberg (Eds.), Handbook of the Economics of Innovation (Vol. 2, pp. 833–872). North-Holland.
  • Fare, R., Grosskopf, S., Norris, M., & Zhang, Z. (1994). Productivity growth, technical progress, and efficiency change in industrialized countries. The American Economic Review, 84(1), 66–83.
  • Farrell, M. (1957). The measurement of productive efficiency. Journal of the Royal Statistical Society, Series A, General, 120(2), 253–282. https://doi.org/10.2307/2343100
  • Feenstra, R., Inklaar, R., & Timmer, M. (2015). The next generation of the penn world table. American Economic Review, 105(10), 3150–3182. https://doi.org/10.1257/aer.20130954
  • Gault, F. (2023). The Oslo manual and standards. In F. Gault, A. Arundel & E. Kraemer-Mbula (Eds.), Handbook of innovation indicators and measurement (pp. 12–17). Edward Elgar Publishing.
  • Gerschenkron, A. (1962). Economic backwardness in historical perspective 1962. Cambridge MA.
  • Goldstone, J. (2002). Efflorescences and economic growth in world history: Rethinking the “rise of the west” and the industrial revolution. Journal of World History, 13(2), 323–389. https://doi.org/10.1353/jwh.2002.0034
  • Gollin, D. (2002). Getting income shares right. Journal of Political Economy, 110(2), 458–474. https://doi.org/10.1086/338747
  • Hall, P., & Soskice, D. (Eds). (2004). Varieties of capitalism: The institutional foundations of comparative advantage (p. 560). Oxford University Press.
  • Hume, D. (1742). Writings in economics. Advance online publication. Rotwein, E. (Ed.). University of Wisconsin Press, 1955.
  • Inklaar, R., & Timmer, M. (2013). Capital, labor and TFP in PWT8. 0. University of Groningen (unpublished).
  • Johnson, S., Larson, W., Papageorgiou, C., & Subramanian, A. (2013). Is newer better? Penn world table revisions and their impact on growth estimates. Journal of Monetary Economics, 60(2), 255 274. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jmoneco.2012.10.022
  • Johnson, P., & Papageorgiou, C. (2020). What remains of cross-country convergence? Journal of Economic Literature, 58(1), 129–175. https://doi.org/10.1257/jel.20181207
  • Jorgenson, D., & Vu, K. (2005). Information technology and the world economy. The Scandinavian Journal of Economics, 107(4), 631–650. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1467-9442.2005.00430.x
  • Keller, W. (2002). Geographic localization of international technology diffusion. American Economic Review, 92(1), 120–142. https://doi.org/10.1257/000282802760015630
  • Keller, W. (2004). International technology diffusion. Journal of Economic Literature, 42(3), 752–782. https://doi.org/10.1257/0022051042177685
  • King, R., & Levine, R. (1994). Capital fundamentalism, economic development, and economic growth. Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy (Vol. 40, pp. 259–292). North-Holland.
  • Kremer, M., Willis, J., & You, Y. (2022). Converging to convergence. NBER Macroeconomics Annual, 36(1), 337–412. https://doi.org/10.1086/718672
  • Kumar, S., & Russell, R. (2002). Technological change, technological catch up, and capital deepening: Relative contributions to growth and convergence. American Economic Review, 92(3), 527–548. https://doi.org/10.1257/00028280260136381
  • Kunieda, T., Okada, K., Sawada, Y., & Shibata, A. (2021). On the two catching-up mechanisms in Asian development. Asian Development Review, 38(2), 31–57. https://doi.org/10.1142/S0116110521500074
  • Lin, J., & Monga, C. (2011). Growth identification and facilitation: The role of the state in the dynamics of structural change. World Bank policy research WP 5313.
  • Los, B., & Timmer, M. (2005). The ‘appropriate technology’ explanation of productivity growth differentials: An empirical approach. Journal of Development Economics, 77(2), 517–531. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jdeveco.2004.04.001
  • Lucas, R. (2000). Some macroeconomics for the 21st century. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 14(1), 159–168. https://doi.org/10.1257/jep.14.1.159
  • Malerba, F., & Lee, K. (2020). An evolutionary perspective on economic catch-up by latecomers. Industrial and Corporate Change.
  • Malmquist, S. (1953). Index numbers and indifference surfaces. Trabajos de Estadística, 4(2), 209–242. https://doi.org/10.1007/BF03006863
  • Mankiw, N., Phelps, E., & Romer, P. (1995). The growth of nations. Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 1995(1), 275–326. https://doi.org/10.2307/2534576
  • Nell, K. (2020). Evaluating the conditional convergence hypothesis in the post-1989 globalization period. Applied Economics, 52(30), 3308–3326. https://doi.org/10.1080/00036846.2019.1710451
  • Nelson, R., & Pack, H. (1999, July). The Asian miracle and modern economic growth theory. The Economic Journal, 109(457), 416–436. https://doi.org/10.1111/1468-0297.00455
  • Pandey, N., de Coninck, H., & Sagar, A. (2022). Beyond technology transfer: Innovation cooperation to advance sustainable development in developing countries. Wiley Interdisciplinary Reviews: Energy and Environment, 11(2), e422. https://doi.org/10.1002/wene.422
  • Park, G., & Dreamson, N. (2023). The heterogeneous effects of human development and good governance on mobile diffusion in the sub-Saharan region: Evidence from panel quantile regression. Technological Forecasting and Social Change, 189, 122355. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.techfore.2023.122355
  • Patel, D., Sandefur, J., & Subramanian, A. (2021). The new era of unconditional convergence. Journal of Development Economics, 152, 102687. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jdeveco.2021.102687
  • Pérez-Trujillo, M., & Lacalle-Calderon, M. (2020). The impact of knowledge diffusion on economic growth across countries. World Development, 132, 104995. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.worlddev.2020.104995
  • Perilla, J. (2019). Mainstream and evolutionary views of technology, economic growth and catching up. Journal of Evolutionary Economics, 29(3), 823–852. https://doi.org/10.1007/s00191-019-00606-1
  • Perilla, J. (2020). Testing the impact of technology diffusion and innovation on long-run growth using cointegration techniques. The Journal of International Trade & Economic Development, 29(6), 748–773. https://doi.org/10.1080/09638199.2020.1729229
  • Pomeranz, K. (2000). The great divergence: China, Europe, and the making of the modern world economy. Princeton University Press.
  • Pritchett, L. (1997). Divergence, big time. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 11(3), 3–17. https://doi.org/10.1257/jep.11.3.3
  • Pritchett, L. (2000a). The tyranny of concepts: CUDIE (cumulated depreciated investment effort) is not capital. Journal of Economic Growth, 5(4), 361–384. https://doi.org/10.1023/A:1026551519329
  • Pritchett, L. (2000b). Understanding patterns of economic growth: Searching for hills among plateaus, mountains, and plains. The World Bank Economic Review, 14(2), 221–250. https://doi.org/10.1093/wber/14.2.221
  • Rodrik, D. (2011). The future of economic convergence. National Bureau of Economic Research working paper no. w17400.
  • Romer, P. (1986, October). Increasing returns and long-run growth. Journal of Political Economy, 94(5), 1002–1037. https://doi.org/10.1086/261420
  • Romer, P. (1993). Idea gaps and object gaps in economic development. Journal of Monetary Economics, 32(3), 543–573. https://doi.org/10.1016/0304-3932(93)90029-F
  • Roy, S., Kessler, M., & Subramanian, A. (2016). Glimpsing the end of economic history?. Unconditional convergence and the missing middle income trap, center for global development working paper 438, 2016.
  • Sachs, J., & Warner, A. (1995). Economic reform and the process of global integration, brookings papers on economic activity.
  • Sebbesen, A. (2023). Technology diffusion across regions. WU Vienna University of Economics and Business.
  • Spence, M. (2011). The next convergence: The future of economic growth in a multispeed world. Farrar, Straus and Giroux.
  • Stokey, N. (2015). Catching up and falling behind. Journal of Economic Growth, 20(1), 1–36. https://doi.org/10.1007/s10887-014-9110-z
  • Tomizawa, A., Zhao, L., Bassellier, G., & Ahlstrom, D. (2020). Economic growth, innovation, institutions, and the great enrichment. Asia Pacific Journal of Management, 37(1), 7–31. https://doi.org/10.1007/s10490-019-09648-2
  • Tucker, J. (1776). Four tracts on political and commercial subjects (3rd ed.). Reprint, Augustus M. Kelley Publishers 1974.
  • Veblen, T. (1915). Imperial Germany and the industrial revolution. Sentry Press.
  • Wade, R. (1996). Japan, the World Bank, and the art of paradigm maintenance: “The East Asian Miracle” in political perspective. New Left Review, (I/217), 3.
  • Young, A. (1995, August). The tyranny of numbers: Confronting the statistical realities of the East Asian growth experience. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 110(3), 641–680. https://doi.org/10.2307/2946695