10,901
Views
2
CrossRef citations to date
0
Altmetric
Guest Editorial

In Defense of the deep state

ABSTRACT

The term “deep state” originally referred to the hidden security bureaucracies in countries like Turkey and Egypt with sinister overtones. The term has been applied by American conservatives to the existing permanent US bureaucracy, which they argue is exerting tyrannical control over citizens and needs to be destroyed root and branch. The fact is that the US administrative state is highly transparent and plays a critical role in delivering services and outcomes that citizens demand. Modern government cannot function without a high degree of delegation to bureaucratic agents; as such the US “deep state” needs to be defended and not vilified. There are several critical mechanisms for democratic principals to exert control over bureaucratic agents. While there are instances of bureaucratic over-reach, the US system provides a number of checks on agency power that are under-utilised. A separate problem lies in under-delegation, where political principals write detailed rules constraining bureaucratic autonomy in ways that hinder effective and timely government action. Future efforts by conservatives to undermine the “deep state” will result in grave weakening of American government and return the country to the 19th century patronage system.

Introduction

This article seeks to defend the idea of an American “deep state”. The phrase “deep state” originated in countries like Turkey and Egypt, where a complex of military and security agencies manipulated the political system and operated in a completely non-transparent way to affect politics. This phrase was then appropriated by American conservatives like Steve Bannon and used to characterise the American bureaucracy; total destruction of the “deep state” has become a central agenda item for many populists on the right.

The United States does not have a “deep state” in the Middle Eastern sense of the term. It has a large and complex civil service at federal, state, and local levels that is responsible for providing the bulk of the services that citizens expect from their government, what is known as the “administrative state”. This administrative state is in fact highly transparent when compared to those of other liberal democracies, not to speak of Middle Eastern dictatorships, and it can be readily controlled by elected political leaders if the latter choose to exercise their powers. That bureaucracy necessarily operates independently of its political masters, however, since elected leaders cannot possibly specify the thousands of daily decisions that are needed to keep the government running. They delegate authority to bureaucrats, which is what we call bureaucratic autonomy.

Protecting a sphere of bureaucratic autonomy is extremely important if the government is to function properly. In this article, I want to defend the continuing need for an administrative state that is allowed to exercise a wide degree of judgement in its implementation of the people’s will. We do not want elected politicians to make decisions, for example, on setting interest rates or deciding which banks to bail out, to determine schedules for Air Force aircraft maintenance, or to certify particular drugs as safe and effective. When politicians start to make these kinds of interventions, the results are almost always harmful because they do not have the expertise or knowledge to do so effectively, and will be tempted to use these powers for their own narrow advantage. Nor do we want those politicians to constrain bureaucratic decision-making excessively by issuing thousands of ex ante rules; bureaucratic red tape is one of the great scourges of government.

On the other hand, we do not want bureaucrats to make big decisions regarding policy. In a liberal democracy, citizens elect leaders who are responsible for setting the overall direction of policy: how much money to allocated to guns versus butter; what kinds of social services the state should offer; or when and where to use military force. This issue is a sore point for many conservatives, since bureaucrats as a group tend to lean to the left in their political preferences. Finding the right degree of bureaucratic autonomy is one of the biggest challenges in any modern liberal democracy.

Why delegation?

In democratic theory, the people are sovereign and have the authority to make decisions regarding their own self-government. They are the principals in a principal-agent hierarchy in which they choose representatives via elections, who then issue mandates to the agencies and bureaucrats responsible for carrying out the people’s wishes. Democratically chosen political principals should control bureaucratic agents.

The problem with this theory is that this simple normative hierarchy has never been possible to implement in practice. As Herbert Simon and his co-authors (Simon, Citation1957) pointed out many decades ago, authority in bureaucracies often flows in the opposite direction. Bureaucratic agents often have the detailed knowledge and expertise that political principals lack, and therefore end up instructing the latter on necessary policies and their requirements for implementation. This reverse hierarchy was parodied in the BBC comedy from the 1980s “Yes Minister” (subsequently “Yes Prime Minister”), where Humphrey, the senior bureaucrat, is portrayed as playing his minister like a puppet master.

There are other important reasons why substantial delegations of authority are necessary for the functioning of any bureaucracy. As Friedrich Hayek pointed out many years ago (Hayek, Citation1945), the vast majority of information in any modern society is local in nature. Hayek in this article was concerned with price-setting in a market economy, but his observation applies to bureaucratic decision-making as well. It is the low-level agents and not their higher level bosses who have best access to local knowledge, and are therefore best able to understand and interact with their environment. They are able to react more quickly to changes in that environment, and, when the proper mechanisms exist, can be held more directly accountable for the decisions they make.

These considerations are apparent in military organisations. One of the reasons the US military has become one of the world’s premiere fighting forces has to do with its adoption of the doctrine of “mission orders” or “commander’s intent” in the course of its post-Vietnam reforms (Fukuyama & Shulsky, Citation1997). This doctrine, based on the German military’s Auftragstaktik, maintains that military commanders should delegate authority to the lowest possible command level consistent with the overall mission. Commanders set broad operational objectives, but it is lower-ranking officers and NCOs in direct contact with the enemy who are responsible for figuring out how to implement those instructions. The effectiveness of this approach to delegated authority can be seen in the success of the US-trained Ukrainian military against their far more centralised Russian foes following Russia’s full-scale invasion of Ukraine in February 2022.

All political systems therefore need to delegate authority, and in many cases, the more delegation, the better the bureaucracy will run. Delegation, however, comes with risks that the agent will make mistakes, take needless risks, be corrupt, or use that authority for purposes other than those intended by the political principal. One of the central issues in administrative law is which authorities to delegate, how much to delegate, and what mechanisms to use to control agencies. In general, the better trained and more professional the agent, the more authority can safely be delegated (Fukuyama, Citation2013, Citation2014), though there is not necessarily optimal degree of delegation that works in all conditions. Furthermore, all bureaucracies necessarily run on a degree of trust.

Trust bureaucrats?

The degree to which different societies are willing to trust bureaucrats varies widely. It is safe to say that those in East Asia exhibit the highest degree of trust. One of the deepest Chinese cultural traditions has to do with the training and respect given to bureaucrats; meritocratic recruitment into the bureaucracy in China goes back a couple of millennia, and the practice has spread to other societies in that country’s cultural sphere of influence like Japan and South Korea.

At the other end of the scale are numerous low-income countries with corrupt or low-capacity governments, which are often seen as predatory or serving the interests of hidden elites. Among developed democracies, most European nations have relatively high degrees of trust in government, though levels are higher in the north and western parts of the region. The United States is something of an outlier among developed democracies, given its deep tradition of anti-statism (Lipset, Citation1995). Many Americans across the ideological spectrum are suspicious of government despite their dependence on the state for many essential services. For this reason, the American state developed later than its European counterparts, has been less extensive in scope, and has had to survive numerous efforts to roll back its authority.

The concept of a modern state was articulated most notably by Max Weber at the turn of the 20th century (Weber, Citation1968). In contrast to patrimonial states that were the outgrowth of the ruler’s household and were staffed by the latter’s friends and family, a modern state is impersonal, treating subjects as equal citizens and serving public interest rather than the private interest of the ruler. Weber understood the ideal type of bureaucrat as a non-partisan, expert administrator, a public servant who was given autonomy and oriented towards public interest.

The early American state was not modern in Weber’s sense, particularly after the 1828 election that brought Andrew Jackson to power. Jackson is often described as the father of American populism, having benefited from the expansion of the franchise to all white males that occurred in most US states during the 1820s. It turned out that individualised benefits like a bottle of bourbon or a job in the post office were the easiest ways to mobilise masses of new voters; Jackson argued that ordinary Americans were qualified to run the government, and that he should get to appoint them since he won the election. Thus began the period of American history known as the “patronage” or “spoils” system, under which virtually every federal employee owed his job to a politician (Skowronek, Citation1982). This system was modernised only in the 1880s with the passage of the Pendleton Act, which established a US Civil Service Commission that sought to introduce merit-based hiring and promotion. While this effort to professionalise the US bureaucracy was largely consolidated by the time of the First World War and expanded with the New Deal’s proliferation of federal agencies, political appointees continue to be much more common in the US than in the democracies of Europe or Asia.

Indeed, the administrative state has been the target of conservatives for decades now, who allege that the country is being ruled by secretive bureaucracy that has escaped the control of democratically elected leaders (Hamburger, Citation2014; Metzger, Citation2017). Many present-day American populists have defined their political objective as the total destruction of the “deep state”. This agenda surfaced briefly at the end of the Trump administration in 2020, when the White House issued Executive Order 13,957 creating a “Schedule F” category of federal employees who could be fired at will, and ordered administrative agencies to move their employees into this designation. While this order was quickly rescinded by the incoming Biden administration, it remains on the agenda of many Republican lawmakers. Some conservative intellectuals maintain that the Pendleton Act was unconstitutional (Howard, Citation2020) and seek to roll back hiring and promotion practices to the kinds of clientelistic practices of the 19th century (Swan et al. Citation2023).

In light of these attacks, it is critical to defend the principle of bureaucratic autonomy, and to define its proper bounds. There is in fact some justice to conservative complaints about an “out-of-control” federal bureaucracy. But in other cases that same bureaucracy is overly constrained, particularly by the masses of ex ante rules and procedures that it has to follow. Those procedures were put in place out of distrust of bureaucratic authority, but they have contributed to the de-legitimising of that same authority because they slow down or block entirely the state’s ability to achieve desirable outcomes.

Delegation in US administrative law

Conservative legal scholars sometimes cite a supposed “non-delegation” doctrine that limits the ability of Congress to delegate authority to administrative agencies. As a constitutional matter, this is highly questionable; no such clause exists in the Constitution (Chabot, Citation2021; Posner & Vermeule, Citation2002). Delegation has been practiced since the first days of the Republic; the first US Congress delegated to Alexander Hamilton’s Treasury Department the job of cleaning up the nation’s Revolutionary War debt. It is a fantasy to think that the American people through their elected representatives can manage a modern government without substantial delegation. They perhaps have in mind the image of a New England town meeting from a couple of centuries ago, where citizens could debate public affairs and play direct roles in local government. This is the way that local government should continue to work today, but it doesn’t work for a federal government that needs to provide services to a country that spans a continent and is home to more than 330 million people.

In US administrative law, there are five basic mechanisms by which political principals can control bureaucratic agents (Bersch & Fukuyama, Citation2023). These include:

  1. Ex ante procedures. The most important of these is the 1946 Administrative Procedure Act (APA), which requires notice-and-comment for any new rule promulgated by an agency (Verkuil, Citation2020). In addition, there are organic laws defining the procedures that agencies much follow in carrying out Congress’ wishes. Examples include the Federal Acquisitions Regulations (FAR) that govern the way the government purchases goods and services, or the voluminous rules regarding Federal employment.

  2. Ex post review. There are numerous mechanisms to enforce bureaucratic accountability, the most important framework for which was established in the 1983 Chevron Deference decision by the Supreme Court (Gluck, Citation2014). The latter imposes a two-stage rule for when the courts can intervene in reviewing bureaucratic decision-making, and limits that intervention on the grounds that the courts in general do not have the expertise to over-rule agency judgements. Chevron Deference has itself become a target of many conservatives, who have chipped away at the ruling through avenues like the “major questions” doctrine. There are numerous other ex post methods for reviewing bureaucratic decisions, such as the APA’s Administrative Judges who can review agency decisions; in addition, Congress frequently holds hearings in which bureaucrats must account for their actions.

  3. Appointment power. In any government, the ability to control personnel is one of the most important means of controlling the bureaucracy. No set of ex ante rules can foresee all possible future states of the world, so human judgement is required to carry out the people’s will in light of changed conditions. The US Constitution specifies that the President may appoint cabinet officers with the “advice and consent” of the Senate, and can set rules for the appointment of “inferior officials”.

  4. Removal power. One might think that removal power is comparable to appointment power, but it has never been the case in US law. The Founding Fathers held a prolonged debate on removals, leading to the “Decision of 1789” wherein the President was given wide latitude to dismiss senior federal officials. James Madison himself argued that, in contrast to appointment power, the ability to remove recalcitrant officials was fundamental to executive authority (Frug, Citation1976). Removal power was weakened for lower level officials, however, in the post-World War II period by the imposition of procedural rules regarding the dismissal of federal workers. These procedures have led to complaints by government managers that it is extremely difficult to hold poorly performing workers accountable.

  5. Ad hoc interventions. There are other legal ways in which political principals can intervene to limit bureaucratic autonomy. The US federal Constitution does not provide for emergency powers, but some state constitutions do, and Congress has enacted a federal emergency powers act. The president can use his pardon power to override executive branch decisions of various sorts, as when former President Trump pardoned Navy SEAL Eddie Gallagher’s conviction by a Navy court.

Bureaucratic overreach

In recent decades, there have been clear cases of bureaucratic overreach, where agencies have arguably gone beyond the statutory authority granted them by Congress. Some examples include:

Sackett v. EPA. Michael and Chantell Sackett were a couple who bought a 0.63 acre lot for a house they planned to build in Priest Lake, Idaho, that was several lots over from the nearest body of water (Adler, Citation2011). At the start of construction, however, they were ordered to desist by the Environmental Protection Agency and the Army Corps of Engineers, who asserted that the lot contained wetlands protected under the Clean Water Act. These agencies employed an extremely broad definition of wetlands and did not allow the Sacketts to contest the judgment in an administrative hearing.

The original statute left unclear what constituted “waters of the United States”. The EPA asserted an extremely broad definition: the land did not have to contain actual navigable waters, but could include dry land that was used by migratory birds. Indeed, the birds did not have to actually use the land; in the words of one commentator, it was enough that “a wayward goose glanced longingly at a given parcel of land” for it to be considered under federal jurisdiction. The Sacketts contested the EPA action in court in a case that went all the way to the Supreme Court. The latter initially decided it in favor of the Sacketts, but on initially on narrow procedural grounds. In May 2023 the Court ruled on the substantive question, saying that the EPA’s definition of its authority was indeed too broad.

A second case of bureaucratic overreach is the expansion of the authority of Title IX. An education bill passed in 1972 had a short clause that prohibited federal funding for entities that discriminated on the basis of gender. In the first couple of decades of Title IX’s existence, it was applied largely to varsity sports on campuses, but in the 2010s it was expanded to cover sexual assault and sexual harassment. By the time of the Obama Administration, the Office of Civil Rights in the Department of Education was issuing hundreds of pages of guidance on how schools and universities were to handle sexual assault cases. These new rules should have been promulgated under the APA and put out for notice and comment. But the OCR issued these rules in the form of “Dear Colleague” letters that were claimed not to have the force of law and were therefore not subject to the APA. Nonetheless, thousands of schools around the US set up Title IX offices according to the federal guidance, for fear of jeopardizing their federal funding. (Melnick, Citation2018)

A third and more recent case concerns the Center for Disease Control and Prevention’s eviction moratorium during the Covid epidemic. At the beginning of the Covid epidemic, the US Congress passed the CARES Act that included a rental eviction moratorium on properties with federal funding or federally-backed mortgages that lasted through July 2020. The CDC then imposed a new moratorium through the end of the year, based on Section 361 of the Public Health Service Act. This was upheld by the pre-Amy Comey Barrett Supreme Court. The Biden administration issued a new moratorium lasting from August through October 2021 in counties with high Covid transmission rates, a ban that was struck down by the new conservative majority on the Court. The latter argued that the authorities delegated by the underlying statute simply did not encompass control over rental housing.

The final case was the one decided by SCOTUS in West Virginia v. EPA in the summer of 2022. The EPA sought to regulate carbon emissions in its 2015 Clean Power Plan, which drew authority from Section 111 of the 1970 Clean Air Act. The plan envisioned “generation shifting” to lower emissions sources, e.g. from coal to natural gas and from natural gas to alternative energy. This would require new investment in clean energy, or in emission allowances under cap-and-trade. Although the Clean Power Plan was rescinded by the Trump administration, it was ultimately withdrawn because market forces on their own were motivating a shift to alternatives without the need for government regulation. Nonetheless, the Roberts court rejected the plan under the “major questions” exception to Chevron Deference, on the grounds that the original statute did not envision giving the EPA authority over greenhouse gas emissions.

The liberal minority on the newly conservative court dissented from the decision on two separate grounds. The first was on the basis of a substantive reading of the original statute, whose language they argued did delegate authority over greenhouse gasses. The second was a procedural one raised by Justice Kagan in her dissent: she argued that the “major questions” exception was a poorly defined concept that the conservative majority was using to insert the court’s public policy preferences in place of those of the expert agency. While the Supreme Court was not explicitly overturning the Chevron decision, it was in gutting its essence by asserting not legislative dominance, but that of the Court itself.

These individual cases underline the real possibilities for excessive autonomy, and there are many others (especially on a state level) that could be added to this indictment. However, it would seem hard to make the case that Americans are living under a tyranny led by out-of-control bureaucrats. America’s Constitutional system of checks-and-balances provides remedies for executive branch overreach, which were ultimately applied by the courts in three of the four cases cited. Progressives may denounce the substantive outcomes of these decisions. The West Virginia v. EPA decision in particular has set a poor precedent for dealing with the urgent problem of carbon emissions. But procedurally, it was clear that the system could check bureaucratic power.

A question of balance

It should be clear that any well-functioning liberal democracy should balance bureaucratic autonomy against the need for democratic accountability; neither extreme of unchecked state authority or thoroughgoing politicisation is appropriate. Finding that balance is, however, can be very challenging.

Take the case of public health during the Covid pandemic. In the early stages of the outbreak, public health authorities, even in red states, were given considerable latitude in setting policies regarding social distancing, shutdowns, masking, and the like. Indeed, the California state constitution granted county health officers final authority in these matters (Lewis, Citation2021). In the first months of the pandemic, there was a widespread view among liberals that it was illegitimate to even consider the existence of a tradeoff between public health and other social goods like jobs or economic growth. As the pandemic evolved, however, public attitudes began to shift. The costs of strict enforcement of shutdowns became more evident, particularly to parents who were frustrated by state-level decisions to keep public schools closed. Covid itself had evolved into less deadly variants, and large parts of the population had been vaccinated. By the end of 2022, China’s “zero-Covid” policy (an even stricter version of US shutdowns) was widely mocked in the US for failing to take into account the economic and social costs of the policy.

These choices then got caught up in the broader political polarisation. There was a backlash against earlier deference to public health authorities and, among some conservatives, conspiracy theories about their underlying intentions. Many red state politicians then moved to the other extreme, passing statutes dictating detailed restrictions on what kind of public health measures could be taken in future outbreaks. These new rules will hobble the ability of public health authorities to flexibly deal with a future crisis.

A proper response to the Covid crisis should have involved the highest political authorities carefully balancing different social goods. Public health authorities should have had significant inputs into this decision, but they should not have been the final arbiters of the tradeoff, since they will typically prioritise maximisation of health over other interests. Unfortunately, under the Trump presidency we did not have a political leader at the federal level who was able or willing to make this decision based on the best available evidence; rather we had a politician who looked primarily to his own re-election interests above all else.

The West Virginia v. EPA decision reflected a similar political failure. The case in my view was procedurally correct but led to a bad outcome, i.e., the failure to regulate, at least in principle, carbon emissions. The fundamental problem lay not in the Supreme Court, but rather in Congress’ failure to legislate on this issue and provide the EPA with proper statutory authority in this domain. In light of this failure, it was understandable that the executive branch tried to extend its authority unilaterally, but also proper for SCOTUS to cut back that authority. Justice Kagan may be correct that the current conservative court was substituting its judgement in place of the expertise of the EPA and Congress, but the courts have been used extensively in recent decades to achieve outcomes that could not be achieved legislatively. Since Brown v. Board of Education, this has largely been the work of progressives, but conservatives have now shown that they can make use of this judicial power as well. In the American system, it is much better to have the elected representatives in Congress make fundamental decisions about tradeoffs between social goods, and then hand off implementation to expert agencies. But the legislative branch has been failing to exercise its proper powers, with bureaucracies and courts then seeking to fill the vacuum.

Under-delegation

In addition to the problem of over-delegation, the United States also suffers from a problem of under-delegation. As noted above, Americans typically don’t trust their bureaucrats, and have consequently wrapped the bureaucracy in layers of procedural controls to hold them accountable. This began with the APA but over the years has extended to virtually all public decisions. Major infrastructure projects, for example, are subject to extensive environmental reviews and public hearings under the National Environmental Policy Act (NEPA), many of which are then duplicated and extended at a state level. Alone among advanced democracies, the United States frequently employs a “right of private action” to enforce its laws, in which individual citizens can act as “private attorneys general” and initiate litigation against parties accused of violating a law (Farhang, Citation2010). This has led to a common-law process in which litigation through (mostly) state courts has steadily expanded the reach and scope of government rules independently of any legislative action.

This steady expansion of procedural checks has led to an outcome I labelled “vetocracy” (Fukuyama, Citation2014), in which veto power is so widely distributed among stakeholders that it becomes extremely difficult to make and implement decisions that serve collective interests. As Nicolas Bagley has pointed out, excessive proceduralism has hobbled government and prevented progressives from using government effectively to achieve their aims (Bagley, Citation2019). On the right, Philip Howard (Citation1996, Citation2014) has inveighed against excessive bureaucratic red tape that defies “common sense” in government decision-making. This logically implies that bureaucrats ought to be given more discretion in implementing legislative mandates, where they can use “common sense” to get to desirable outcomes.

If we are to permit greater bureaucratic autonomy, we still need to put in place strong accountability measures to make sure that autonomy is not abused. One method might be to replace ex ante procedures and the mountains of red tape they impose on bureaucrats, with stronger ex post review as a method of holding agencies accountable. Ex post review can be just as obstructive as ex ante procedures if they are allowed to proliferate endlessly, so we need to find ways of streamlining them. For any bureaucratic system to work, the society would have to make adequate investments in the training and professionalisation of public servants.

Conclusions

The US bureaucracy suffers from any number of dysfunctions, problems that have been analysed at length in a number of detailed studies (Kamarck, Citation2016; National Commission on Military, National, and Public Service, Citation2020; Schuck, Citation2014; Volcker et al., Citation2003). For example, removal power has indeed been hobbled by layers of procedural protections for public servants that have accumulated over the years, making it difficult to discipline poorly-performing workers. Whatever the proper solution, it is not the wholesale destruction of the professional civil service in the manner envisioned by many conservatives today. Schedule F will not solve the problem of political bias in the bureaucracy but will exacerbate it, and will come at the expense of government competence and effectiveness.

Currently, an election and change in administrations leads to the replacement of between 3000–4000 senior officials throughout the Federal government. This is a far higher number than in any other developed democracy, where political turnover leads to a few dozen replacements at most. It is nonetheless normatively in line with democratic theory. The backers of Schedule F envision increasing the number of political appointees to tens or perhaps hundreds of thousands. In their view, the will of elected political principals is being stymied by the left-leaning bias of ordinary civil servants, and conservatives are compiling lists of politically sympathetic candidates to replace them.

This plan will run into several insuperable problems. Ordinary civil servants are today not overtly selected on the basis of their political leanings but on supposedly objective merit criteria. Any political bias exhibited by those selected reflects biases in the underlying populations: people wanting to be public school teachers or are qualified to be university professors tend to lean left; those wanting to be policemen, firemen, or prison guards tend to lean right. Finding enough people who meet political loyalty tests and have appropriate skills will be hard and will severely compromise the quality of public servants. Moreover, conservatives need to think ahead to what will happen if they lose a subsequent election: their proteges will lose their jobs and be replaced not by neutral non-partisan civil servants, but by liberal appointees meeting explicit liberal political tests. This was the nature of American government under the 19th century patronage system prior to passage of the Pendleton Act.

Distrust of government has existed for as long as governments have existed, and in many cases was fully justified by government behaviour. But many contemporary populists have taken this critique to extreme lengths, attacking not just specific abuses of state power, but the very idea of a government built around merit and expertise. They have taken to heart Andrew Jackson’s view that “any ordinary American” could perform the functions of government. This was scarcely true in the 1820s when the federal government did little other than deliver the mail and operate customs houses. But most ordinary Americans today are not capable of managing monetary aggregates, running large-scale predictive weather models, controlling air traffic, teaching at state universities, undertaking employment surveys, or supervising randomised trials for new pharmaceuticals.

Selection of bureaucrats on the basis of merit has been threatened not just from the right, but from the left as well. There are progressive critiques of meritocracy that argue it is a technique used by existing elites to preserve their power and influence; well-educated parents get their children into the right schools and give them a leg up on entering the world of power and influence (Sandel, Citation2020). Progressives have sought to introduce diversity criteria into federal hiring practices to ensure representation of racial and ethnic minorities, women, and other marginalised populations.

From either perspective, abandoning meritocratic hiring and promotion in the US government will have huge consequences for government effectiveness. A recent cross-national study by Perry et al. (Citation2023) shows that there is a strong relationship between meritocratic recruitment and promotion and government performance across a wide variety of agencies and countries. The United States could decide to de-prioritise government effectiveness in favour of greater political control, but it is not clear that this is an outcome favoured by a majority of citizens who are already unhappy with the way the government works.

If people with the requisite skills to run a modern government have political biases, the solution is to mandate different policies, and correct specific instances of overreach rather than demonising the idea of expertise in general. Populists today are simply not aware of the mechanisms available to them to control the “deep state”. Their problem lies in the fact that most of these mechanisms run through a Congress that they do not fully control. As a result they will seek to use executive power to undermine the executive branch itself through a mass purge of civil servants deemed not to be sufficiently loyal to their agenda.

The United States is today engaged in a long-term competition with China. The latter constitutes a civilisation unto itself that for many centuries has been built around high-quality bureaucracy and respect for expertise. What it lacks are institutions that can check its powerful state, like a rule of law and democratic accountability. The United States sits at the other end of the spectrum, with powerful check-and-balance institutions, an expansive but often ineffective state, and a political culture that is very distrustful of state authority. The developed democracies of Europe and East Asia occupy a position somewhere in between, closer to the American than to the Chinese side, but still building on long traditions of state authority. It is hard to see the United States prevailing in this global competition if it prioritises the dismantling of its existing bureaucracy and the replacement of experts by political loyalists. What it needs to strive for in the end is balance, a balance between bureaucratic autonomy and political control, and between procedural compliance and effective outcomes.

Correction Statement

This article has been corrected with minor changes. These changes do not impact the academic content of the article.

Additional information

Notes on contributors

Francis Fukuyama

Francis Fukuyama is Olivier Nomellini Senior Fellow at Stanford University’s Freeman Spogli Institute for International Studies (FSI), and a faculty member of FSI’s Center on Democracy, Development, and the Rule of Law (CDDRL). He is also Director of Stanford’s Masters in International Policy Program, and a professor (by courtesy) of Political Science. This article is based on the annual Donald Stone lecture given to the American Society for Public Administration on March 21, 2023. He can be reached at [email protected]; Twitter @FukuyamaFrancis; website www.francisfukuyama.com.

References

  • Adler, J. (2011). Wetlands, property rights, and the due process deficit in environmental law. Cato Supreme Court Review, 139–165.
  • Bagley, N. (2019). The procedure fetish. Michigan Law Review, 118, 345–401. https://doi.org/10.36644/mlr.118.3.procedure
  • Bersch, K., & Fukuyama, F. (2023). Defining bureaucratic autonomy. Annual Review of Political Science, 26(1), 213–232. https://doi.org/10.1146/annurev-polisci-051921-102914
  • Chabot, C. (2021). The lost history of delegation at the founding. Georgia Law Review, 56, 81. https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.3654564
  • Farhang, S. (2010). The litigation state: Public regulation and private lawsuits in the US. Princeton University Press.
  • Frug, G. (1976). Does the Constitution prevent the discharge of civil service employees? University of Pennsylvania Law Review, 124(4), 942–1012. https://doi.org/10.2307/3311498
  • Fukuyama, F. (2013). What is governance? Governance, 26(3), 347–368. https://doi.org/10.1111/gove.12035
  • Fukuyama, F. (2014). Political order and political decay. Farrar, Straus and Giroux.
  • Fukuyama, F., & Shulsky, A. (1997). The virtual corporation and army organization. Rand Corporation. https://doi.org/10.7249/MR863
  • Gluck, A. (2014). What 30 years of Chevron teach us about the rest of statutory interpretation. Fordham Law Review, 83, 607.
  • Hamburger, P. (2014). Is administrative law unlawful?. University of Chicago Press.
  • Hayek, F. (1945). The Use of Knowledge in Society. The American economic review, 35, 519–530.
  • Howard, P. (1996). The death of common sense. Warner Books.
  • Howard, P. (2014). The rule of nobody: Saving America from dead laws and broken government. W. W. Norton.
  • Howard, P. (2020). “Restoring accountability to the executive branch,” George Mason Center for the study of the administrative state working Paper 20-02.
  • Kamarck, E. (2016). Why presidents fail and how they can succeed again. Brookings Institution.
  • Lewis, M. (2021). The premonition: A pandemic story. W. W. Norton.
  • Lipset, S. M. (1995). American exceptionalism: A double-edged sword. W. W. Norton.
  • Melnick, R. (2018). The transformation of title IX: Regulating gender equality in Education. Brookings Institution Press.
  • Metzger, G. (2017). 1930s redux: The administrative state under siege. Harvard Law Review, 131, 2–95.
  • National Commission on Military, National, and Public Service. (2020). Final report: Inspired to serve USGPO.
  • Perry, J., Oliveria, E., Abner, G., Suzuki, K., Lee, S., & Hur, H. (2023). What does the evidence tell us about merit principles and government performance? Public Administration. https://doi.org/10.1111/padm.12945
  • Posner, E., & Vermeule, A. (2002). Interring the nondelegation doctrine. University of Chicago Law Review, 69(4), 1729. https://doi.org/10.2307/1600617
  • Sandel, M. (2020). The tyranny of merit: What’s become of the common good?. Farrar, Straus and Giroux.
  • Schuck, P. (2014). Why government fails so often and how it can do better. Princeton University Press. https://doi.org/10.1515/9781400850044
  • Simon, H. A. (1957). Administrative behavior: A study of decision-making processes in administrative organization. Free Press.
  • Skowronek, S. (1982). Building a New American state: The expansion of National administrative capacities, 1877-1920. Cambridge University Press.
  • Swan, J., Savage, C., & Haberman, M. (2023). Trump and allies forge plans to increase presidential power in 2025. New York Times. July 17.
  • Verkuil, P. (2020). The administrative procedure Act at 75: Observations and reflections. George Mason Law Review, 28, 533.
  • Volcker, P. (2003). Report of the National Commission on the public Service. USGPO.
  • Weber, M. (1968). Economy and society: An outline of interpretive sociology. Bedminster Press.

Reprints and Corporate Permissions

Please note: Selecting permissions does not provide access to the full text of the article, please see our help page How do I view content?

To request a reprint or corporate permissions for this article, please click on the relevant link below:

Academic Permissions

Please note: Selecting permissions does not provide access to the full text of the article, please see our help page How do I view content?

Obtain permissions instantly via Rightslink by clicking on the button below:

If you are unable to obtain permissions via Rightslink, please complete and submit this Permissions form. For more information, please visit our Permissions help page.