566
Views
0
CrossRef citations to date
0
Altmetric
Finance and Banking Economics

Does financial deleveraging affect governments’ desirability of privatization? Evidence from the Chinese listed local SOEs

, &
Article: 2220468 | Received 10 Jan 2021, Accepted 28 May 2023, Published online: 02 Jun 2023

ABSTRACT

The rapid growth of local SOEs in China largely depends on high leverage, thus local governments and their SOEs will face harder budget constraints when the central bank implements tight credit policies. Using a sample of listed local SOEs in the Chinese A-share market, this paper attempts to investigate the relationship between financial deleveraging and privatization of local SOEs. We find that privatization of the Chinese local SOEs increases significantly during financial deleveraging, and this effect is more pronounced among SOEs with less tax contribution, fewer employees and that cause greater financial burden to the local governments. This paper broadens the research on environmental factors that drive politicians to privatize.

1. Introduction

Although it has been nearly four decades since privatization was introduced into the world, privatization in China is still ongoing. Unlike other transition economies who implemented “shock therapies”, the Chinese government has adopted a gradual privatization strategy (G. M. Chen et al., Citation2006). China’s large-scale privatization took place during 1995 − 2002, which was sanctioned by the central government and actively responded by the local governments. However, relative to the previous period, privatization in China after 2002 continues on a smaller scale and is mainly a decision of local governments absent central government policy. Even so, China has been still one of the most active countries in privatization between 2009 and 2016, and its privatization trade volume has ranked first in the world for many years.Footnote1

As the owners of state-owned enterprises (SOEs), the governments’ willingness to reform will ultimately determine whether privatization happens (K. Guo & Yao, Citation2005). Therefore, existing literature on the causes of the Chinese privatization primarily focuses on government motivations. There are three main points of view: The first line of thinking argues that increasing fiscal revenue or reducing financial burden is the main reason for local governments to privatize their SOEs (D. Li & Lui, Citation2004; Han & Oi, Citation2008; Zhu, Citation2004). The second line of thinking is that the purpose of governments privatizing SOEs is to improve enterprise efficiency (Gupta et al., Citation2008). The third line of thinking supports political motivation. For example, Xia and Chen (Citation2007) and Yang et al. (Citation2010) document that the local governments tend to control large-scale and regulated industry firms. Collectively, these studies merely concentrate on the relationship between government motivation and privatization without considering macro-environment that affects the governments’ willingness to privatize.

Then, do environmental factors affect the governments’ willingness to privatize? Several studies have explored the impact of China’s institutional change on privatization. Cao et al. (Citation1999) argue that reforms in tax, fiscal, monetary and banking systems in the 1990s have hardened the local governments’ budget constraints and triggered the privatization of local SOEs. S. Li et al. (Citation2000) document that cross-regional competition played an important role in driving the local governments to privatize. Brandt et al. (Citation2005) show that banking reform played an integral role in inducing the township and village enterprises to be privatized. H. Li (Citation2003) and K. Guo and Yao (Citation2005) also attribute the privatization to the hardened budget constraints and market competition. Surprisingly, however, there is scarce literature on what drives the Chinese local governments to privatize in the 21st century. Obviously, institutional change mentioned above cannot explain China’s privatization in recent ten years, thus it is of great academic interest to provide new explanation for this, especially in the case that China’s institutional and economic environment is rapidly changing.

In this paper, we study the influence of financial deleveraging on privatization of local SOEs in the past decade. China’s credit supply has exhibited cyclical features since 1998. Typically, the People’s Bank of China (PBC) implements a credit expansion policy in bad times and a credit crunch policy in good times. Following Bezemer and Zhang (Citation2014), we use the method of Hodrick-Prescott filter to identify financial deleveraging and financial leveraging in China. By employing a Logit model and using a sample of listed local SOEs in the Chinese A-share market from 2004 to 2017, we find that financial deleveraging can increase the probability of a local SOE being privatized. In particular, SOEs with less tax contribution, fewer employees and that cause greater financial burden to the local governments are more likely to be privatized during financial deleveraging. Overall, our results indicate that stabilizing tax revenue, minimizing unemployment and reducing financial burden are important considerations for local governments when selecting SOEs to privatize.

Our paper has important theoretical contributions and policy implications. First, the current literature on factors that influence China’s privatization mainly focuses on the local government motivations. Even though several articles explored the impact of institutional changes on privatization, they mainly focus on privatization in the 1990s. By using more recent Chinese privatization data, this paper contributes to this strand of literature by showing that macro environment plays a key role in driving local governments to privatize, and provides a new explanation for privatization in China in the 21st century. Second, it enriches the literature on the consequences of financial deleveraging. The current literature mainly focuses on the macro-effects caused by financial deleveraging by using cross-country data, but our paper is an empirical study on its micro-consequences within one country. Third, our findings indicate that stabilizing finance and keeping employment are important considerations for local governments when making privatization decision. Therefore, the central government, in order to encourage local governments to abandon SOEs that are uncompetitive but pay more taxes, have more loss or redundancy, should deepen reform of fiscal and taxation system and formulate measures to compensate local governments’ loss caused by efficiency-enhancing privatization.

The rest of our paper is organized as follows: Section 2 is the theoretical analysis and research hypothesis; Section 3 describes data sources and research design in detail; Section 4 is empirical analysis, testing the relationship between financial deleveraging and privatization, and which types of SOEs that the local governments are more likely to privatize during financial deleveraging. Robustness checks are presented in Section 5. Section 6 is the concluding remarks.

2. Theory and hypotheses

2.1. Financial deleveraging and privatization of local SOEs

Privatization in China is mainly prompted by local governments (Qian & Weingast, Citation1997). Therefore, financial deleveraging may promote privatization by affecting the governments’ willingness to privatize. In what follows we analyze how financial deleveraging influences local governments’ desirability of privatization.

First, Financial deleveraging has side effects on GDP growth in the short term caused by a reduction of total credit supply in the society (Bernanke & Gertler, Citation1995; Devlin & McKay, Citation2008; International Monetary Fund, Citation2008; Ma et al., Citation2016), as reforms usually occur when external environment becomes unfavorable, so local governments will seek reform strategies to support economic growth. In particular, China’s unique fiscal decentralization that requires the local governments to share most of their tax revenue with the central government but take the main responsibility for local public expenditure makes the local governments face strong budget constraints. The local governments need to obtain more fiscal revenue through economic development in order to provide public services and maintain social stability. More importantly, the promotion of local officials in China is in the hands of the central government who usually uses economic indicators such as regional economic growth and fiscal revenue to evaluate the performance of local officials (H. Li & Zhou, Citation2005; Y. Chen et al., Citation2005). As a result, the local governments in China have a higher initiative to pursue economic growth. Developing private economy is conducive to enhancing economic growth (Barnett, Citation2000; Berkowitz & DeJong, Citation2003; Patrick, Citation1997) and improving local fiscal conditions (Zhu, Citation2004). Therefore, local governments have incentives to increase support for the private economy, and privatizing SOEs can make this support more credible.

Second, Financial deleveraging will harden the budget constraints of local SOEs. The Chinese local governments’ implicit guarantee for local SOEs has induced soft budget constraints problems for a long time. Specifically, SOEs with lower profitability and even loss can still survive through bank loans and pay taxes to the local governments (K. Guo & Yao, Citation2005). Financial deleveraging in large part reflects the central government’s intentions who often exerts influence on the PBC’s decision-making (Chen and Zha, Citation2018). In order to avoid being punished, not only the banks quickly respond to the credit policies, but also the local governments reduce their intervention in the credit allocation. Then, banks strengthen their risk awareness and are motivated to allocate scarce credit resources to more profitable and efficient firms. This fact is supported by Cong et al. (Citation2019), they show that more capital was allocated to firms with higher productivity during the credit crunch period, but stimulus-driven credit expansion reverses this allocation process. Hardened budget constraints make it difficult for the local governments to finance the inefficient SOEs and they have to use their own financial resources to keep the SOEs survive (Cao et al., Citation1999), which will cause a heavy financial burden to the local governments and hence reduce their willingness to control such SOEs.

Third, Financial deleveraging can reduce social consumption and increase demand uncertainty in the short term. Less capital supply and higher costs of debt induce liquidity problems. As a response, firms may reduce investment, hold down wages and even lay off workers (Ma et al., Citation2016), which is followed by a decline in demand for consumer goods. According to the view of informational gains, private enterprises respond more quickly to consumer demand, input costs and other information compared with public-owned enterprises (Glaeser & Scheinkman, Citation1996; Gupta et al., Citation2008). Therefore, the local governments are more likely to privatize their SOEs to improve the flexibility of firms’ management when the SOEs are subject to demand shock, which is conducive to enhancing enterprise efficiency and increasing tax revenue.

In summary, financial deleveraging puts the local governments into a disadvantaged position through slowing economic growth, hardening SOEs’ budget constraints and reducing social demand in the short run, which will discourage their willingness to control SOEs and thus privatization may take place. On the basis of arguments above, this paper proposes the following hypothesis:

H1:

Financial deleveraging has a positive effect on the probability of a local SOE being privatized.

2.2. Heterogeneous effects of financial deleveraging on privatization of local SOEs

In China, fiscal revenue of local governments mainly comes from taxes and government funds——income from auction of state-owned land (Q. Guo, Citation2019). The slowdown of economic growth and the decline of social demand reduce the sales and profits of firms when financial deleveraging occurs. In addition, the capital investment of the firms will also decline due to the reduction of credit loans, leading to lower wages and higher unemployment (Cuerpo et al., Citation2015). As a result, the local governments’ revenue from value added taxes related to sales activity and income taxes related to business or personal income can fall significantly. Bernanke and Gertler (Citation1995) document that the impact of tight monetary policy on household demand is first reflected in housing investment of a family, causing a sharp decline in housing demand. In China, financial deleveraging is always accompanied by tight monetary policy, so it can be reasonably inferred that financial deleveraging will lead to a decline in housing demand and affect the local governments’ revenue stemming from government funds. Therefore, the local governments have a strong incentive to try their best to stabilize the taxes from SOEs because they are easier to be controlled. So, how to reduce tax loss as much as possible while promoting privatization? As the information asymmetry between SOEs and the local governments is lower relative to private firms, it is difficult for SOEs to evade taxes by hiding income (Liu & Li, Citation2012). From this point of view, a rational local government will choose to control the SOEs that make more tax contribution. Therefore, we propose the following hypothesis:

H2:

Relative to the SOEs with more tax contribution, the SOEs with less tax contribution are more likely to be privatized by local governments during financial deleveraging.

High regional unemployment rate may hinder the political promotion of local officials. Therefore, how to minimize unemployment is usually a key issue for local governments in the process of privatization. Hu et al. (Citation2006) document that privatization in China is not accompanied by higher unemployment, which probably implies that local governments in China considered employment problem in advance (D. Li & Lui, Citation2004) and choose to privatize SOEs first with fewer employees. D. Li and Lui (Citation2004), Hu et al. (Citation2006), Xia and Chen (Citation2007) and Yang et al. (Citation2010) find that governments tend to retain the large SOEs and privatize the small ones. Given the rise in unemployment during financial deleveraging, the Chinese local governments’ preference for this kind of privatization sequencing should be more prominent. In view of this, we propose our third hypothesis:

H3:

Relative to the SOEs with more employees, the SOEs with fewer employees are more likely to be privatized by local governments during financial deleveraging.

In addition to increase revenue, saving expenditure can also help alleviate the fiscal pressure faced by the Chinese local governments during financial deleveraging. Therefore, the SOEs that create high fiscal pressure for the local governments are likely to be privatized first. Bai et al. (Citation2006) find that privatizing unsustainable SOEs can reduce the financial burden of local governments. D. Li and Lui (Citation2004) indicate that the local governments would like to privatize SOEs only when the huge debts and losses of the SOEs needed to be borne by the government. Huang (Citation2019) shows that the purpose of local governments privatizing SOEs is not to improve the performance of SOEs but to reduce subsidies to them. Combining the views of these literature, we think that only the loss itself does not necessarily lead to privatization of local SOEs. Profit-losing SOEs may have higher sales income and still be able to pay value added taxes (K. Guo & Yao, Citation2005), or profit-losing SOEs are still able to access to bank loans and do not need the assistance of local governments. Therefore, if the profit-losing SOEs rely on the assistance of local governments to operate, with the fiscal pressure increasing during financial deleveraging, the local governments are likely to privatize them to get rid of the burden. Based on the arguments above, this paper proposes the following hypothesis:

H4:

The SOEs with more losses and more government subsidies are more likely to be privatized by the local governments during financial deleveraging.

3. Research design

3.1. Sample selection and data sources

The initial sample of this paper includes all the listed SOEs in the Chinese A-share market from 2004 to 2017. The China Securities Regulatory Commission (CSRC) has required all listed companies to disclose the information of controlling shareholders and ultimate owners since 2003, so we choose 2004 as the starting point of our sample period in order to observe the annual change of the ultimate owners of firms. Ultimate owners and financial data of sample firms mainly come from the China Stock Market and Accounting Research (CSMAR) database, which provides comprehensive data on China’s capital market. The data of regional GDP, value of the secondary industry, value of import and export trade, and unemployment rate come from the Economic Statistical Yearbook of each province. The data of credit to private sector (credit to households and credit to non-financial corporations) comes from the World Development Indicators (WDI) database of the world bank, in which we can get China’s credit data from 1977. In order to generate a more precise time trend and define financial deleveraging accurately, we use the Chinese credit data from 1977 to 2017. We exclude the following kinds of firms: (1) Firms in the financial industry; (2) Public utility firms; (3) Firms controlled by the central government; (4) ST, PT and insolvent firmsFootnote2; (5) Firms in industries and province (Tibet) that have never experienced privatization during the sample period; (6) Firms with missing data for major variables. Thus, 8,485 observations of 1,009 firms make up our final sample, and 208 observations of privatization are included. All continuous variables are winsorized at 1 percent in order to reduce the estimation errors caused by extreme values.

3.2. Regression model and variable measures

In order to test the impact of financial deleveraging on the privatization of local SOEs, we estimate the following regression model at the firm-year level:

(1) Privatizationi,t=α+β1Deleveragei,t+β2Strategyi,t+β3PastROAi,t+β4LnStaffi,t1+β5Growthi,t1+β6Levi,t1+β7Efficiencyi,t1+β8Structurei,t+β9Opennessi,t+β10Unemploymenti,t+β11VOLi,t+Industry+Province+εi,t(1)

Where Privatization is an indicator variable that equals one if the ownership of the local SOE i is transferred to private entitiesFootnote3 in year t, and zero otherwise.

Deleverage denotes financial deleveraging. Following Bezemer and Zhang (Citation2014), we use the financial deleveraging year dummies (Del_Dum) generated by the extent to which credit to private sector/GDP (Debt/GDP) deviates from its long-term trend to measure Deleverage. Specifically, we first use the Hodrick-Prescott filter (HP) with a smoothing parameter of 400 to separate the trend and cyclical component in Debt/GDP. The cyclical component is the deviation of Debt/GDP from its trend and is denoted by Cycle. Cycle being positive means the credit is expanded, and otherwise the opposite. Then, we calculate the standard deviation of Cycle, namely σ(Cycle). When Cycle is negative and its absolute value is more than ασ (Cycle) with α = 1, we define the year as a local trough of the credit cycle. Finally, we define the local peaks of the credit cycle in which the cyclical component Cycle is higher than in both the previous and posterior year. Years between the peak and the trough (excluding the peak year) are defined as financial deleveraging years, for which the variable Del_Dum takes value one, and zero otherwise.Footnote4 Since Del_Dum is a year-dummy variable, it may capture other time trend factors as well as financial deleveraging. In order to eliminate the proxy errors, we also use Debt/GDP as the explanatory variable and observe whether there is a negative correlation between Debt/GDP and Privatization, so that Debt/GDP and Del_Dum can complement each other.

Control variables. According to the literature on causes of privatization or privatization sequencing, we include control variables reflecting firm characteristics as follows: an indicator of strategic industry (Strategy),Footnote5 average profitability over the past two years (PastROA), number of employees (LnStaff), sales growth rate (Growth), interest-bearing debt ratio (Lev) and employee productivity (Efficiency). Then, regional variables including industrial structure (Structure), openness (Openness) and unemployment (Unemployment) are controlled as well. Generally speaking, local governments are more open-minded and have greater support for private economy in areas with high industrialization and opening up, while they may oppose privatization in areas with high unemployment because employment issues affect their political promotion. In addition, financial leverage volatility (VOL) has a negative impact on economic growth and aggravates financial uncertainty (Ma et al., Citation2016), which may affect the privatization of local SOEs, so we also control for it. Finally, we control for industry and province effects by using dummy variables, and cluster standard errors at the firm level. Detailed definitions of the variables used in the baseline regressions are shown in .

Table 1. Variable definitions.

4. Empirical results

4.1. Descriptive statistics

Panel A presents the result of descriptive statistics. The mean value of Privatization is 0.025, indicating that 2.5 percent of local SOEs in our sample are privatized. Del_Dum has a mean value of 0.567, implying an even distribution of our samples in years of financial deleveraging and financial leveraging. The mean value of Strategy is 0.222, suggesting that 22.2 percent of local SOEs in our sample belong to strategic industries. PastROA has a mean value of 0.019, indicating that the average profitability of local SOEs over the past two years is 1.9 percent higher than the industry mean value. The sales growth rate has a mean value of 18 percent but has a standard deviation of 0.442, implying that the growth of local SOEs has a significant variation. The interest-bearing debt ratio ranges from −0.394 to 0.568, suggesting that some local SOEs’ interest-bearing debt ratio are lower but others are higher than industry mean, so the leverage level of local SOEs varies greatly.

Table 2. Descriptive statistics of main variables.

Panel B reports the results of difference test for Privatization and Debt/GDP by Del_Dum. 3.5 percent of local SOEs are privatized in years of financial deleveraging——the mean value of Privatization is 0.035 when Del_Dum = 1, while 1.5 percent of local SOEs are privatized in years of financial leveraging——the mean value of Privatization is 0.015 when Del_Dum = 0. The mean difference test for Privatization shows a significant difference, indicating that more local SOEs are privatized in financial deleveraging years than in financial leveraging years, which implies the positive relationship between financial deleveraging and privatization again. In addition, the mean value of Debt/GDP in financial deleveraging years (113.806% when Del_Dum = 1) is significantly lower than in financial leveraging years (141.787% when Del_Dum = 0), suggesting that the financial leverage ratio is lower in deleveraging years and the variable Debt/GDP can complement Del_Dum well.

4.2. Regression results of financial deleveraging and privatization of local SOEs

reports the results from estimating model (1).Footnote6 Columns (1) and (2) show the estimations of the effect of financial deleveraging on privatization with only the industry fixed effect and province fixed effect. In Columns (3) and (4), we add other control variables to the regressions. The results in Columns (1) and (3) show that in financial deleveraging years, the probability of local SOEs being privatized by the governments increases significantly at the 1% level. Since the coefficient estimated by Logit regressionFootnote7 has no practical meaning and given that Del_Dum is a variable with values of 0 and 1, we can calculate its odds ratio, which is 1.84 and 2.30 respectively, suggesting that the odds ratio of privatization of local SOEs increases by 84%−130% in financial deleveraging years compared to financial leveraging years. The results in Columns (2) and (4) show that the lower the financial leverage ratio, the more likely are the local SOEs to be privatized. By calculating the marginal effect of Debt/GDP, we find that the probability of privatization of local SOEs will increase by 52%−60% relative to the sample average (0.025) if Debt/GDP reduces 30% (the difference between the mean value of Debt/GDP when Del_Dum = 1 and Del_Dum = 0). Moreover, privatization also reflects the determination of the local governments to reform SOEs and will have a profound impact on the beliefs of the public and economic prospects. Together with results in , we conclude that the effect of financial deleveraging on privatization is large.

Table 3. Financial deleveraging and privatization of local SOEs.

4.3. Regression results of heterogeneous effects of financial deleveraging on privatization of local SOEs

The empirical findings thus far show that financial deleveraging can significantly increase the probability of privatization of local SOEs, the question we want to explore next is what types of SOEs the local governments tend to privatize. According to the theoretical analysis above, tax contribution, unemployment and financial burden may be important factors that local governments concern about in the privatization decision. Therefore, in order to test hypotheses 2, 3 and 4, we estimate the following three regression models respectively:

(2) Privatizationi,t=α+β1Deleveragei,t+β2LowTaxi,t+β3Deleveragei,tLowTaxi,t+βjControls+εi,t(2)
(3) Privatizationi,t=α+β1Deleveragei,t+β2LowStaffi,t+β3Deleveragei,tLowStaffi,t+βjControls+εi,t(3)
(4) Privatizationi,t=α+β1Deleveragei,t+β2Lossi,t+β3Subsidyi,t+β4Lossi,tSubsidyi,t+β5Deleveragei,tLossi,t+β6Deleveragei,tSubsidyi,t+β7Deleveragei,tLossi,tSubsidyi,t+βjControls+εi,t(4)

Where LowTax denotes that a firm contributes less to taxation, which is an indicator variable that equals one if the average tax paid by the firm in the past year is lower than the industry’s annual median, and zero otherwise. LowStaff denotes that a firm has fewer employees, if the number of employees in the firm in the past year is less than the industry’s annual median, we make LowStaff equal one and zero otherwise. Loss denotes the natural logarithm of the average loss of the firm over the past three years, but we make Loss equal zero if the average EBIT (earnings before interest and taxes) of the firm over the past three years is positive. Subsidy denotes the natural logarithm of the average government subsidies a firm has obtained over the past three years. Controls denotes control variables that are similar to model (1), and standard errors are clustered at the firm level as well.

Panel A reports the results from estimating model (2). As shown, the coefficient for the interaction term of Del_Dum and LowTax in Column (1) is 0.670, which is positive and significant at the 5% level. The coefficient for the interaction term of Debt/GDP and LowTax in Column (2) is −0.022, which is negative and significant at the 5% level. Collectively, Panel A Columns (1) and (2) suggest that compared with local SOEs with more tax contribution, local SOEs with less tax contribution are more likely to be privatized by governments during financial deleveraging. Thus, hypothesis 2 is supported. Panel B reports the results from estimating model (3). As shown, the coefficient for the interaction term of Del_Dum and LowStaff in Column (1) is 0.590, which is positive and significant at the 10% level. The coefficient for the interaction term of Debt/GDP and LowStaff in Column (2) is −0.020, which is negative and significant at the 10% level. Taken together, Panel B Columns (1) and (2) demonstrate that compared with local SOEs with more employees, local SOEs with fewer employees are more likely to be privatized by governments during financial deleveraging, which is consistent with hypothesis 3.

Table 4. Financial deleveraging, tax contribution/scale of employees and privatization of local SOEs.

Columns (1) and (4) show the estimations of the interaction effect of financial deleveraging and firm loss on privatization. The results show that neither the coefficient for the interaction term of Del_Dum and Loss in Column (1) nor the coefficient for the interaction term of Debt/GDP and Loss in Column (4) is significant. Then, we argue that loss itself does not lead to privatization of a local SOE, this is inconsistent with the argument that SOEs with poor performance are first privatized (Gupta et al., Citation2008). Columns (2) and (5) show the estimations of the interaction effect of financial deleveraging and government subsidies on privatization. As shown, neither the coefficient for the interaction term of Del_Dum and Subsidy in Column (2) nor the coefficient for the interaction term of Debt/GDP and Subsidy in Column (5) is significant. Results in Columns (2) and (5) indicate that firms with more government subsidies are not necessarily privatized by the local governments. Columns (3) and (6) are the results from estimating model (4) in which we include the interaction term of Del_Dum (Debt/GDP), Loss and Subsidy. We notice that the coefficient of Del_Dum*Loss*Subsidy in Column (3) is 0.010, which is positive and significant at 5% level. Meanwhile, the coefficient of Debt/GDP*Loss*Subsidy in Column (6) is −0.0002, which is negative and significant at 10% level. Overall, results in demonstrate that only the SOEs with more losses and more government subsidies can be privatized by the local governments. In other words, during financial deleveraging, the local governments are willing to privatize SOEs only when the SOEs’ losses cause financial burden to them. Our evidence is consistent with the findings obtained by D. Li and Lui (Citation2004), which suggest that the heavy debt of a SOE will promote the government to make the decision of privatization when it becomes a major financial burden to the government.

Table 5. Financial deleveraging, financial burden and privatization of local SOEs.

In addition to separately run models (2)−(4), we also run a general model that includes all the variables (LowTax, LowStaff, Loss and Subsidy) together to see if these variables have some kind of interaction among themselves. The results are reported in . As shown in Columns (1) and (3), our main conclusions do not change when we run a general model. That is, local SOEs with less tax contribution, fewer employees and more losses and subsidies have a higher privatization probability during financial deleveraging. However, the coefficients of Del_Dum*LowTax (Debt/GDP*LowTax) and Del_Dum*LowStaff (Debt/GDP*LowStaff) are smaller than that in while the coefficient of Del_Dum*Loss*Subsidy (Debt/GDP*Loss*Subsidy) is similar to that in . Such results indicate that the variables of taxes and employees may have some kind of interaction, but which does not affect the estimate of the correlation among financial deleveraging, tax contribution (scale of employees) and privatization of local SOEs. Columns (2) and (4) report the relative importance (RI)——calculated as the share in explaining dependent variable variance——of each variable, which show that financial burden caused by SOEs is the most important factor that local governments consider when deciding to privatize what types of SOEs. However, The RIs of LowTax and LowStaff have no significant difference, indicating that taxes and employees are equally important to the governments.

Table 6. Relative importance of tax contribution, scale of employees and financial burden.

5. Robustness tests

5.1. Substitution of financial deleveraging

First, although credit to private sector scaled by GDP is widely used to measure financial leverage ratio, some literature also adopts M2/GDP as a proxy variable for financial leverage ratio in robust tests. Therefore, we use the HP with a smoothing parameter of 400 to separate the trend and cyclical component in M2/GDP and regenerate the financial deleveraging year dummies, denoted by Del_Dum2. Then, we re-estimate model (1), the result is shown in Column (1), we note that the coefficient of Del_Dum2 is positive and significant at the 1% level. Second, we substitute M2/GDP for Debt/GDP. The result in Column (2) shows that M2/GDP correlates negatively with Privatization, suggesting an increase in the privatization when the money supply decreases, which is consistent with our main results.

Table 7. Regression results based on substitution of financial deleveraging, Placebo test and IV estimation.

5.2. Placebo test

Because financial deleveraging influences all listed local SOEs, thus we cannot observe the counterfactual situation——privatization of the local SOEs that are not affected by financial deleveraging. To further confirm the robustness of our main results, we perform a placebo test with defining a set of false financial deleveraging years. Specifically, we define 2009 and 2012 − 2016 (they are actually financial leveraging years) as the financial deleveraging years, denoted by Del_Dumfalse. If the coefficient of Del_Dumfalse is consistent with that of Del_Dum in in terms of direction and significance, then we can say that our main results are not robust, and robust otherwise. Column (3) indicates that the coefficient of Del_Dumfalse is −0.396, which is contrast to the results in . Therefore, our main results hold.

5.3. Endogeneity

Some unobservable factors may influence China’s financial deleveraging and privatization of local SOEs at the same time. For example, the capital supply is usually insufficient in bad times, resulting in a decline in the credit to private sector. Meanwhile, the local governments are usually under higher fiscal pressure in bad times, and their willingness to privatize SOEs may increase. To address our concern for endogeneity issue, we employ an instrumental variable probit (IV Probit) approach. We designate the annual average shadow interest rate (SSR) in the United States as the instrumental variable for the Chinese financial deleveraging. There are two reasons: First, global factors such as federal shadow interest rate have spillover effects on the monetary policies of emerging market countries (He & McCauley, Citation2013). It will lead to capital outflow from emerging markets when the US Federal Reserve raises interest rates, and hence financial deleveraging may happen in these economies. Therefore, the US shadow interest rate meets the correlation requirements of IV. Second, the US shadow interest rate will not directly affect the privatization of local SOEs in China, meeting the exogenous requirements of IV. Columns (4) and (5) present the results of IV Probit. As shown, the relationship between Del_Dum (Debt/GDP) and Privatization still exists.Footnote8

Another endogeneity may be caused by the control variables. That is, the same control variables that have influence on the probability of privatization may also have some effects on the value of the deleveraging decisions taken by China’s Central Bank concerning the individual firms. To address such endogeneity issue, we first regress financial deleveraging variables (Del_Dum and Debt/GDP) on the control variables used in the baseline model, and obtain the residual terms——denoted by ResidualDel_Dum and ResidualDebt/GDP, respectively. Then, we regress Privatization on the residual terms (ResidualDel_Dum and ResidualDebt/GDP). Doing so enables us to obtain the net effects of financial deleveraging on privatization because the residual term represents the portion of the deleveraging variable that is not affected by the control variables. reports such net effects. As shown, the coefficients of ResidualDel_Dum in Columns (1) and (2) are significantly positive, and the coefficients of ResidualDebt/GDP in Columns (3) and (4) are significantly negative, indicating that the endogeneity issue caused by the control variables does not change our conclusions.

Table 8. Regression results that remove the effects of control variables on deleveraging.

5.4. Sample selection bias

Given that the local SOEs with certain characteristics may have a high probability of being privatized, which can cause estimation bias, we match the SOEs that are privatized with the SOEs that are not privatized employing the propensity score matching method (PSM). The variables used for matching include strategic industry dummy, ROA over the past two years, number of employees, sales growth, interest-bearing debt ratio and employee productivity. We use one-to-four nearest neighbor matching and the difference between the propensity scores of treatment firms and control firms is no more than 0.005. The results are presented in Columns (1) and (2). In addition, we also employ Mahalanobis distance (MD) method to match firms, and the results are reported in Columns (3) and (4). As shown, with either matching method, our main results still hold.

Table 9. Regression results based on propensity score and MD matched sample.

5.5. Other robustness tests

China has been confronted with the complex and changeable environment during the long period from 2004 to 2017, our main results may be driven by external shocks or other domestic reforms. Therefore, we attempt to eliminate the impact of some special events. For example, we remove the observations in 2007 and 2008 from our sample to exclude the possible influence of the global financial crisis. In addition, the central government proposed to actively develop a mixed ownership economy at the Eighteen Third Plenary Session in 2013, which may affect the subsequent transfer of state-owned equity. To address this concern, we add the dummy variable after2013 (1 for the years after 2013, and 0 for other years) in the model (1). The unreported results show that the relationship between Del_Dum (Debt/GDP) and Privatization still exists.

6. Conclusions

Privatization is an effective means for China to reform SOEs and establish a market-oriented economy. However, mass and rapid privatization supported by economic liberals is not applicable for transition economies. The success of privatization in large part depends on the perfection of law and the effectiveness of regulation (Estrin et al., Citation2009). Given that China’s legal system is imperfect and protection of investors is weak, it is reasonable for the Chinese government to adopt the gradual privatization strategy. However, with the improvement of China’s legal system, the privatization of SOEs in China will continue. In particular, the central government has put forward guidance on the reform of SOEs by classification since 2015, which implies that most of the state-owned capital will be invested in the areas related to the public service, strategic security and vitals of the national economy. Meanwhile, the SOEs will follow the market rules of survival of the fittest and withdraw from the competitive field. Therefore, we need to deeply understand what and how environmental factors affect the local governments’ desirability of privatization and the local governments’ key concerns in the privatization decision in order to promote the local governments to withdraw their SOEs from the fields that lack competitive advantages.

Using a sample of listed local SOEs in the Chinese A-share market from 2004 to 2017, our paper investigates the influence of financial deleveraging on privatization of local SOEs in China. Our results show that the probability of privatization of local SOEs increases significantly in financial deleveraging years, and the lower the financial leverage ratio, the greater is the possibility of privatization of local SOEs. Therefore, our paper is consistent with the notion that privatization is influenced by environmental factors. In addition, financial deleveraging has heterogeneous effects on privatization across firms. Specifically, the local SOEs with less tax contribution, fewer employees, and that cause greater financial burden to the local governments are more likely to be privatized during financial deleveraging, suggesting that stabilizing tax revenue, minimizing unemployment and reducing financial burden are important concerns of local governments in the privatization decision.

Our results have two important implications. First, previous literature has explored the impact of environmental factors——such as intensified market competition, tax sharing and banking reform and interregional competition——on Chinese privatization. Consistent with these literatures, we find that macro environment is an important factor affecting the privatization of Chinese local SOEs from the perspective of financial deleveraging. As a result, the willingness of the Chinese local governments to privatize varies in different macro-environments, and the researchers should not only focus on the local government motivations of privatization but also the environmental factors that affect the local government motivations of privatization when they study the causes of Chinese privatization in the future. Second, the Chinese central government can force their local governments to withdraw from fields that lack competitive advantages through appropriate macro policies, and hence promote the reform of local SOEs. However, our results indicate that the Chinese local governments may selectively retain large SOEs that contribute a lot to taxation but are inefficient or even suffer heavy losses to obtain fiscal and political benefit. Therefore, in order to promote more efficient privatization, the Chinese central government should also deepen reform of the fiscal and taxation systems and formulate measures to compensate for the losses caused by efficient privatization to local governments.

Acknowledgments

The views expressed herein are the authors’ own and do not necessarily reflect those of Wuhan University. In addition, no potential conflict of interest was reported by the authors.

Disclosure statement

No potential conflict of interest was reported by the author(s).

Additional information

Funding

This paper was supported by the National Natural Science Foundation of China (No.71803146), Humanities and Social Sciences Research Project of the Ministry of Education of China (No. 19YJA630093), and the Fundamental Research Funds for the Central Universities in Wuhan University (No. 2019IVB004)

Notes on contributors

Weiwei Yang

Weiwei Yang is a lecturer in the School of Business and Tourism Management at Yunnan University, China. Her research interests include corporate governance, capital market accounting, and effects of macroeconomic policies on firm behavior. Her works appear in journals including Annals of Economics and Finance, Emerging Markets Finance and Trade.

He Wang

He Wang is a senior economist. He has engaged in financial market related work at China Construction Bank from July 2013 to October 2022. At present, he engages in public utility related work at the Geriatrics Hospital of Yunnan Province. His research interests include financial intermediation, and Chinese economy. His works appear in the Chinese journals including Chinese Public Administration, China Rural Survey.

Huobao Xie

Huobao Xie is a professor in the Economics and Management School at Wuhan University, China. His research interests include corporate governance, capital market accounting, and Chinese economy. His works appear in the Chinese journals including Accounting Research, Auditing Research, Management Review, Business Management Journal, etc.

Notes

1 The data is from Privatization Barometer Database, www.privatizationbarometer.net. The amount of transactions in the database refers to the funds raised by share issue privatization (SIP) and private equity, including both partial and full privatization.

2 ST (special treatment) refers to firms that suffer losses for two consecutive years, and PT (particular transfer) refers to firms that suffer losses for three consecutive years. Insolvent refers to firms with total liabilities greater than total assets.

3 We define the ultimate owner as a local state entity if the code of its nature in the CSMAR database is 1100 (i.e., state-owned enterprises), 2000 (i.e., administrative organs and institutions) and 2120 (i.e., local institutions), and otherwise we define it as a private entity.

4 The unreported results show that 2004 − 2008, 2010, 2011 and 2017 are financial deleveraging years.

5 We define the military, power grid, petroleum and petrochemical, telecommunications, coal, civil aviation and shipping industry as strategic industries.

6 The privatized firms are only 2.45% (208/8485) in our sample, so privatization is a rare event. Following King and Zeng (Citation2001), we use the relogit command to modify the Logit model and find results similar to .

7 Probit model is also used for the analysis of binary dependent variable issues, so we also use Probit to estimate model (1). The unreported results show that variables’ marginal effects, model’s goodness of fit and model’s percent of correctly predicted is very similar to that of Logit. Given that Del_Dum is a variable with values of 0 and 1, we chose Logit to perform our regression analyses because it allows us to calculate the odds ratio of Del_Dum. Thus, we could easily explain the economic effect of deleveraging on SOEs’ privatization.

8 The Wald test shows that Del_Dum and Debt/GDP are endogenous. In addition, SSR has strong explanatory power for both Del_Dum and Debt/GDP. We also conduct a two-stage estimation and find that the F value of the first stage is far more than 10, so there is no weak IV problem.

References

  • Bai, C. E., Lu, J., & Tao, Z. (2006). The multitask theory of state enterprise reform: Empirical evidence from China. The American Economic Review, 96(2), 353–20. https://doi.org/10.1257/000282806777212125
  • Barnett, S. (2000). Evidence on the fiscal and macroeconomic impact of privatization. International Monetary Fund Working Paper, https://www.imf.org/en/Publications/WP/Issues/2016/12/30/Evidenceon-the-Fiscal-and-Macroeconomic-Impact-of-Privatization-3692.
  • Berkowitz, D., & DeJong, D. N. (2003). Policy reform and growth in post-Soviet Russia. European Economic Review, 47(2), 337–352. https://doi.org/10.1016/S0014-2921(02)00186-1
  • Bernanke, B. S., & Gertler, M. (1995). Inside the black box: The credit channel of monetary policy transmission. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 9(4), 27–48. https://doi.org/10.1257/jep.9.4.27
  • Bezemer, D., & Zhang, L. (2014). From boom to bust in the credit cycle: The role of mortgage credit. 27th Australasian Finance and Banking Conference 2014 Paper, https://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=2484715.
  • Brandt, L., Li, H., & Roberts, J. (2005). Banks and enterprise privatization in China. Journal of Law, Economics, & Organization, 21(2), 524–546. https://doi.org/10.1093/jleo/ewi022
  • Cao, Y., Qian, Y., & Weingast, B. R. (1999). From federalism, Chinese style to privatization, Chinese style. The Economics of Transition, 7(1), 103–131. https://doi.org/10.1111/1468-0351.00006
  • Chen, G. M., Firth, M., & Rui, O. M. (2006). Have China’s enterprise reforms led to improved efficiency and profitability? Emerging Markets Review, 7(1), 82–109. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ememar.2005.05.003
  • Chen, Y., Li, H., & Zhou, L. (2005). Relative performance evaluation and the turnover of provincial leaders in China. Economics Letters, 88(3), 421–425. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.econlet.2005.05.003
  • Chen, K., & Zha, T. (2018). Macroeconomic effects of China’s financial policies. NBER Working Paper. http://www.nber.org/papers/w25222
  • Cong, L. W., Gao, H., Ponticelli, J., & Yang, X. (2019). Credit allocation under economic stimulus: Evidence from China. The Review of Financial Studies, 32(9), 3412–3460. https://doi.org/10.1093/rfs/hhz008
  • Cuerpo, C., Drumond, I., Lendvai, J., Pontuch, P., & Raciborski, R. (2015). Private sector deleveraging in Europe. Economic Modelling, 44, 372–383. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.econmod.2014.07.034
  • Devlin, W., & McKay, H. (2008). The macroeconomic implications of financial ‘deleveraging’. Economic Round-Up, 113(4), 47–73. https://search.informit.org/doi/10.3316/INFORMIT.746486448074636
  • Estrin, S., Hanousek, J., Kocenda, E., & Svejnar, J. (2009). The effects of privatization and ownership in transition economies. Journal of Economic Literature, 47(3), 699–728. https://doi.org/10.1257/jel.47.3.699
  • Glaeser, E., & Scheinkman, J. (1996). The transition to free markets: Where to begin privatization. Journal of Comparative Economics, 22(1), 23–42. https://doi.org/10.1006/jcec.1996.0002
  • Guo, Q. (2019). The potential fiscal effects and risk prevention of the tax cut and fee reduction. Management World (Monthly), 6, 1–10. https://doi.org/10.19744/j.cnki.11-1235/f.2019.0075
  • Guo, K., & Yao, Y. (2005). Causes of privatization in China: Testing several hypotheses. The Economics of Transition, 13(2), 211–238. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1468-0351.2005.00221.x
  • Gupta, N., Ham, J. C., & Svejnar, J. (2008). Priorities and sequencing in privatization: Evidence from Czech firm panel data. European Economic Review, 52(2), 183–208. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.euroecorev.2007.05.004
  • Han, C., & Oi, J. (2008). Fiscal motivation for property restructurings of public enterprises in China. Economic Research, 2, 56–67. (in Chinese).
  • He, D., & McCauley, R. N. (2013). Transmitting global liquidity to East Asia: Policy rates, bond yields, currencies and dollar credit. BIS Working Papers, https://www.bis.org/publ/work431.htm.
  • Huang, Y. (2019). Solve the problem or escape responsibility? the politics of Chinese privatization reform. Chinese Political Science Review, 4(1), 1–27. https://doi.org/10.1007/s41111-018-0110-6
  • Hu, Y., Song, F. M., & Zhang, J. (2006). Does privatization work in China? Economic Research, 7, 49–60. (in Chinese).
  • International Monetary Fund. (2008). Global financial stability report: Containing systemic risks and restoring financial soundness. https://www.imf.org/External/Pubs/FT/GFSR/2008/01/.
  • King, G., & Zeng, L. (2001). Explaining rare events in international relations. International Organization, 55(3), 693–715. https://doi.org/10.1162/00208180152507597
  • Li, H. (2003). Government’s budget constraint, competition, and privatization: Evidence from China’s rural industry. Journal of Comparative Economics, 31(3), 486–502. https://doi.org/10.1016/S0147-5967(03)00070-2
  • Li, S., Li, S., & Zhang, W. (2000). The road to capitalism: Competition and institutional change in China. Journal of Comparative Economics, 28(2), 269–292. https://doi.org/10.1006/jcec.2000.1653
  • Li, D., & Lui, F. (2004). Why do governments dump state enterprises? Evidence from China. NBER East Asia Seminar on Economics, 12. http://www.nber.org/chapters/c10190
  • Liu, X., & Li, X. (2012). Pyramid structure, tax burden and enterprise value: Evidence from local state-owned enterprises. Management World (Monthly), 8, 91–105. (in Chinese). https://doi.org/10.19744/j.cnki.11-1235/f.2012.08.009
  • Li, H., & Zhou, L. (2005). Political turnover and economic performance: The incentive role of personnel control in China. Journal of Public Economics, 89(9), 1743–1762. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jpubeco.2004.06.009
  • Ma, Y., Tian, T., Ruan, Z., & Zhu, J. (2016). Financial leverage, economic growth, and financial stability. Journal of Financial Research, 6, 37–51. (in Chinese).
  • Patrick, P. (1997). Privatization and economic growth: An empirical investigation from a sample of developing market economies. Applied Economics, 29(2), 161–178. https://doi.org/10.1080/000368497327245
  • Qian, Y., & Weingast, B. R. (1997). Federalism as a commitment to preserving market incentives. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 11(4), 83–92. https://doi.org/10.1257/jep.11.4.83
  • Xia, L., & Chen, X. (2007). Marketization, SOE reform strategy, and endogenously determined corporate governance structure. Economic Research, 7, 82–95. (in Chinese).
  • Yang, J., Lu, D., & Yang, D. (2010). State-owned enterprises’ government control right transfer. Economic Research, 2, 69–82. (in Chinese).
  • Zhu, H. (2004). The effects of interregional competition and fiscal incentives on privatization in China. Economic Research, 10, 24–34. (in Chinese).