751
Views
0
CrossRef citations to date
0
Altmetric
Labour Economics and Education

Legacy of the Czar: Complementarity between education and work in Russia

& ORCID Icon
Article: 2230623 | Received 19 Mar 2021, Accepted 21 Jun 2023, Published online: 03 Jul 2023

ABSTRACT

Vocational school graduates enjoy a higher employment probability than other types of graduates across industrial economies. This may result from either the signaling effects of vocational school degrees or skill complementarity between vocational schooling and work experience. Regarding wage regressions, signaling effects should make the coefficient of the interaction term between years of schooling and work experience negative, whereas complementarity between education and work experience should increase this coefficient because the cross-derivative of output with respect to schooling and work experience is positive. Thus, the negativity of the interaction term between years of schooling and work experience decreases as schooling becomes more complementary to work. We find that the negativity of the interaction term is smaller for vocational track graduates than for general track graduates in Russia. This result is arguably because the Russian vocational track emphasizes complementarity between education and work to a greater degree than its general track.

1. Introduction

Among major advanced economies, the United States (US) and Japan have unstratified elementary and secondary education systems that offer general education to most youth through the upper-secondary level. In contrast, continental European nations have stratified systems that track pupils in general and vocational secondary students after their elementary or junior secondary levels (Allmendinger, Citation1989; DiPrete et al., Citation2017; Glaesser & Cooper, Citation2011; Han, Citation2016; Kerckhoff, Citation2001; Pfeffer, Citation2008).

Research has shown that European stratified systems may reproduce and enhance existing social stratification (Han, Citation2016; Kupfer, Citation2010; Mijs, Citation2016; von Below et al., Citation2013). Furthermore, van de Werfhorst (Citation2011) used a cross-national dataset from continental European nations to demonstrate that the skills acquired on the vocational track do not offset the disadvantages faced by students on this track and that the reproduction of social stratification between generations is embedded even in informal networks. Using a German dataset, Roth (Citation2018) found that an informal social network that connects parents helps children join company-sponsored training programs to enter occupations that correspond to the social status of their parents.

Although Biewen and Thiele (Citation2020) showed that parents with a higher social status are better able to correct for mismatches in their children’s early careers, this result does not contradict the hereditary feature of stratification demonstrated by Roth (Citation2018).

However, this result does not exclude the possibility that vocational education equips students with skills that are more complementary to those acquired in the workplace than the skills gained by those on the general track. When controlling for other factors, the acquisition of vocational education has contributed to a higher occupational status (Bol & van de Werfhorst, Citation2011). Moreover, Heisig and Solga (Citation2015) showed that an emphasis on vocational skills in upper-secondary education tended to improve the numeracy skills of students on lower tracks.

Using a Spanish dataset, Murillo et al. (Citation2012) reported declining but positive returns on vocational education and attributed the decline to mismatches between education and the skills actually required in workplaces. Additionally, using a Spanish dataset, Blázquez et al. (Citation2019) found that participation in training programs during unemployment improved the probability of employment. Although this result does not directly support the formal vocational tracking of children, it does indicate the possible benefits of vocational education prior to entry into the workforce. Using a Romanian dataset, Popescu and Roman (Citation2018) concluded that participation in vocational training modestly increased the probability of employment. Additionally, reforms to extend the general education content of the vocational track do not necessarily improve labor market outcomes in either Sweden (Hall, Citation2016) or Croatia (Zilic, Citation2018).

Regarding the nature of stratification due to tracking, the heterogeneity across nations is substantial. Forster and Bol (Citation2018), for instance, showed that vocational track students in the Netherlands demonstrated higher levels of performance. Additionally, Prokic-Breuer and Dronkers (Citation2012) reported that the Dutch vocational track seems to increase the overall academic performance of Dutch pupils compared with the vocational tracks of students in Germany and Switzerland.

Choi et al. (Citation2019) illustrated two possible, countervailing effects of stratified vocational education systems. Using data from the Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD) countries, Choi et al. (Citation2019) found that graduates of the vocational track lagged in terms of labor market outcomes in the long term – an effect that is likely to capture the reproduction of social stratification – but experienced better employment opportunities immediately after graduation – an effect that likely captures successful skill acquisition in the vocational track and its signaling effects. However, this employment premium for vocational school graduates attenuates over time.

As European vocational schools are often linked with training programs sponsored by the corporate sector, such as the apprenticeship schemes in Germany (Solga & Konietzka, Citation1999; Witte & Kalleberg, Citation1995) and the partnerships between vocational schools and the corporate sector in Russia (Marques et al., Citation2020), the European vocational track appears to offer a particularly salient or immediate form of complementarity between schooling and work experience that may improve productivity.

We test this conjecture by using data from Russia, where the education system is deeply stratified (T. P. Gerber, Citation2003). Our identification strategy involves evaluating the relative strength of skill complementarity effects compared with signaling effects. As the innate abilities of workers are private information when they join the market after graduation, employers use observable information such as educational background as a signal of abilities, which is also referred to as the “sheepskin” effects of a degree (Hansen et al., Citation1970; Heywood, Citation1994; Olfindo, Citation2018; Spence, Citation1973; Temple, Citation2002; van der Meer, Citation2011; Waldman, Citation1984; Waldman et al., Citation2013). As workers acquire work experience, employers gradually learn about their innate abilities from information related to their outputs, career paths, and promotions (Waldman, Citation1984). Therefore, the signaling impact of schooling is high in the early stages of one’s career and then gradually attenuates (Habermalz, Citation2006).

This attenuation process, which is called employer learning, is typically observed as a negative coefficient for the interaction term between years of schooling and years of work experience in a Mincerian wage equation for which the dependent variable, wages, is represented by a logarithmic term (Farber & Gibbons, Citation1996). Empirical results, especially those based on US datasets, support this theoretical prediction (Altonji & Pierret, Citation2001; Lange, Citation2007; Pinkston, Citation2006; Schönberg, Citation2007). Data from China, which has a stratified education system, similarly support the employer learning hypothesis (Wang & Li, Citation2020).

While employer learning effects are observed to be unambiguous in the US, they are not necessarily observed to be so in Germany. Bauer and Haisken DeNew (Citation2001) and Lluis (Citation2005), using a German dataset, found that employer learning effects, if they existed, were very weak in Germany. We suggest that one possible explanation of the results of weakly observed employer learning in the European context by Bauer and Haisken DeNew (Citation2001) and Lluis (Citation2005) is the complementarity between European vocational schooling and work experience. To identify the complementarity between vocational education and work, we examine whether the coefficient of this interaction term is greater than the coefficient of the interaction term for general schooling and work experience. Neither Bauer and Haisken DeNew (Citation2001) nor Lluis (Citation2005) differentiated years of schooling between the general and vocational tracks, so this possibility has not been tested in Germany. In this paper, we test this possibility for Russia.

Notably, our aim is to identify the relative effects of the complementarity between schooling and (future) work experience, which are priced in the labor market, against the signaling effects. To identify the signaling effects in isolation, datasets such as the National Longitudinal Surveys of Youth in the US, which include information on IQ that is unknown to employers but is known to researchers, are useful because researchers can assume that IQ is a proxy for one’s innate ability. Such information is unknown to employers when workers join the market after graduation. By using such data, researchers can identify the signaling effects that are conditional on IQ, as presented by Farber and Gibbons (Citation1996); Altonji and Pierret (Citation2001); Pinkston (Citation2006); Schönberg (Citation2007); Lange (Citation2007). However, as we want to estimate the complementarity effects that are conditional on the signaling effects, it suffices to estimate the coefficient of the interaction term between years of schooling and years of work experience. Thus, our identification strategy does not require proxies for innate abilities that are unknown to employers but known to researchers, such as IQ.

Essentially, a Mincerian wage regression estimates the relative price of schooling in a hedonic setting rather than the returns on education investment (Heckman et al., Citation2006, Citation2008). However, our interest is in whether the market values the signaling or complementarity effects of schooling. Thus, despite the concerns suggested by Heckman et al. (Citation2006), we believe that an estimation of the complementarity between schooling and work experience in a Mincerian setting is conceivable.

Our focus and identification strategy also diverge from previous works that either explicitly or implicitly address the complementarity of vocational schooling with work, such as Bol and van de Werfhorst (Citation2011); Murillo et al. (Citation2012); Popescu and Roman (Citation2018); Choi et al. (Citation2019). Bol and van de Werfhorst (Citation2011) recognized vocational schools’ signaling of their possible complementarity with work when workers enter the market. Murillo et al. (Citation2012); Popescu and Roman (Citation2018); Choi et al. (Citation2019) also found positive impacts of vocational schooling on labor market outcomes in workers’ early stages after graduation, thereby also indicating signaling effects. Our interest is, instead, in the complementarity between vocational schooling and work experience that materializes over time through work experience and hence in the increasing rather than declining positive impacts on labor market outcomes.

The remainder of this paper is organized as follows. Section 2 reviews the Russian education system and places it in a historical and comparative context alongside other continental European countries. Section 3 presents our identification strategies and predictions. Section 4 introduces the dataset used in this study, Section 5 presents the empirical results, and Section 6 concludes the paper.

2. Historical and comparative context

2.1. A stratified system and its origin

The nine mandatory years of schooling in Russia consist of primary education from the first to the fourth year and general education from the fifth to the ninth year. Students then choose between two tracks, general and vocational. Students who choose the general track proceed to general upper-secondary education for two years followed by university-level education for four or five years. Students who choose the vocational track proceed to vocational upper-secondary school for three years followed by technical tertiary education. Although this sequence is the basic structure, some students move between these two tracks. For instance, students who have graduated from vocational school may enter related university programs or departments (Nikolaev & Chugunov, Citation2012, p. 1, 19–33, 39–45, 48–57).

The creation of the Russian stratified education system dates back to the reign of Peter the Great in the early 18th century. Peter’s move to extend education was part of his Westernization reforms that predominantly focused on vocational training. The vocational track of secondary education in Russia originated with his reforms (Bannatyne & Hall, Citation1998; Okenfuss, Citation1973). Based on this legacy, apprenticeships in industries were transformed into systematic training programs and linked to modernized vocational schooling in industrialization from the late 19th century (Magsumov, Citation2018, Citation2019; Meyser, Citation2004).

The Russian Revolution of 1917 did not displace the legacy of Czarist Russia but rather strengthened it. Secondary vocational schools were expanded to prepare the workforce for industrialization in the former USSR (Holmes, Citation1973), and the vocational upper-secondary and tertiary tracks were further extended in the 1950s and 1960s, as was the general tertiary education track. This development resulted in Russian education becoming highly stratified and its vocational education being even more extensive than Germany’s vocational education program (T. P. Gerber & Hout, Citation1995; Heyneman, Citation1997, Citation1998).

Even after the collapse of the USSR, the government continued to treat the technical and vocational track as the core of public education (Heyneman, Citation1997; Wallenborn, Citation2010). Despite the dissolution of the ideological cohesion that dominated the Soviet education system (Heyneman, Citation2000; Zajda, Citation2003), the stratified education system continued to dominate (Heyneman, Citation1997). In fact, empirical studies have indicated that the strong links between stratified educational tracks and the first occupations for which the tracks were designed did not essentially change (T. P. Gerber, Citation2003).

Although the vocational programs that were sponsored by state-owned enterprises under the Soviet regime have contracted (Kotásek, Citation1996), partnerships between private companies and local governments have been reorganized along with the privatization of enterprises and the decentralization of educational policy making (Marques et al., Citation2020; Walker, Citation2006).

2.2. European context

Vocational education systems are inevitably linked to labor market institutions. If workers were free to move without institutional constraints designed to prevent poaching, then employer investment in worker skills would be significantly discouraged. Thus, a certain level of restriction or coordination in labor markets is likely to increase the investment in training programs, such as apprenticeships, that are sponsored by companies or industrial bodies.

Western Europe and Russia share a history of imposing various restrictions on the mobility of workers such as apprentices since early modern times (Stanziani, Citation2009a, Citation2009b). Furthermore, Austria-Hungary and Germany referenced the Russian system when modernizing their vocational education systems, typically in metalworking and electrical engineering enterprises such as Schuckert, MAN, Krupp, Siemens, and Bosch, from the 1890s to the 1910s (Wiemann, Citation2004). The interdependence of vocational education and market coordination is not only historical, as even now, vocational education systems appear to perform more effectively in the more coordinated labor markets of Western Europe and Russia (Bol & van de Werfhorst, Citation2011).

In facing the challenge of globalization, the European consensus is to not concede in implementing the unstratified education system shared by the US and Japan. Instead, European nations are struggling to update their historical legacy of vocational education to keep pace with technological changes (The European Centre for the Development of Vocational Training, ed, Citation2004a, Citation2004b; Powell et al., Citation2012). As Western Europe and Russia share a history of vocational education, a study on Russia has European-wide relevance.

2.3. Current educational and labor market outcomes

The stratified education system implies that educational achievement when completing the lower-secondary level strongly affects one’s educational trajectory and occupational choices (Cherednichenko, Citation2012, Citation2013; The European Centre for the Development of Vocational Training, ed, Citation2004b). Because of the stratified education system, students in vocational upper-secondary schools exhibit significantly lower academic performance than students in general upper-secondary schools (Amini & Nivorozhkin, Citation2015).

Moreover, research indicates that differences in educational achievement significantly predict mortality rates (Perlman & Bobak, Citation2008) as the stratified education tracks match occupational choices and perceived social class, and it is this difference that leads to different life expectancies (Bessudnov et al., Citation2012). Additionally, graduates of the vocational track are more likely to drink alcohol and use drugs than graduates of the general track (Stothard et al., Citation2007; Wall et al., Citation2011). Therefore, as in other countries, the Russian stratified education system is likely to enhance social stratification.

However, vocational education on its own appears to benefit workers. For example, Marques et al. (Citation2020) found growth in the partnerships between local governments and the private sector for vocational training and concluded that vocational education not only coincides with lower youth unemployment but is also considered an opportunity for young workers to learn skills from the private sector.

3. Identification strategy

3.1. Employer learning

Consider a production technology

(1) logyi,tSi,Xi,t,μi=α1Si+α2Xi,t+α3Xi,t2+α4SiXi,t+α5μi+ξi,t(1)

where yi,tSi,Xi,t,μi denotes the output of worker i in period t, which is a function of worker i's years of schooling, Si, years of labor market experience in period t, Xi,t, and innate ability that is hidden to employers, μi, and the variance of logyi,t is Varlogyi,t=σξ2. Since μi is not observable to employers at the time of graduation, employers predict output yi,t+1 as a function of the perceived ability of worker i,

(2) logwi,t=Elogyi,t|Ii,t+ϵi,t(2)

where the information set Ii,t={Si,Xi,t,μˆi,t1}. In practice, given the technology presented as in EquationEquation (1), employers set wages given Si, Xi,t, and μˆi,t such that

(3) logwi,t=C+α1Si+α2Xi,t+α3Xi,t2+α4SiXi,t+α5μˆi,t+ i,t(3)

Since employers do not have any information about past output yi,t1 in period 1, they use available information about Si as a signal of the ability of worker i such that

(4) Ii,0=Si.(4)

Moreover, employers know from experience that Si is a noisy signal such that

(5) μi=C+Si+ωi,(5)

where Eω=0 and the variance of ω is Varω=σω2, which leads to

(6) μˆi,0=C+Si.(6)

After the first period, employers observe residual ri,t between the true production technology (1) and wage function (3) based on their prediction such that

(7) ri,tlogyi,tSi,Xi,t,μiα1Si+α2Xi,t+α3Xi,t2+α4SiXi,t=α5μi+ξi,t.(7)

At the end of each period t, firms use the information provided by ri,t to update the prior estimate of ability μˆi,t1. The information set used to estimate ability from period t=1 onward is thus Ii,t={Si,Xi,t,yt1,μˆi,t1}. For simplicity, let us assume that noises of educational backgrounds and past outputs as signals of abilities follow the normal distribution and have identical variances, σξ2=σω2. Then, by a Bayesian model of learning about an unknown parameter when the errors are normal (Bartels, Citation2002; A. Gerber & Green, Citation1999),μˆi,t is expanded as (see section A.1 in the appendix for the derivation)

(8) μˆi,t=tt+1μˆi,t1+1t+1ri,t=1t+1μˆt,0+1t+11tri,t=1t+1C+Si+1t+11tμi+ξi,t=1t+1C+Si+tt+1μi+1tξi,tt+1.(8)

EquationEquation (8) means that the weight of the initial estimate of ability μˆi,0=C+Si on wage wi,t decreases by updating information even if it was as informative as output in early periods. This decrease in the weight of μˆi,0=C+Si is the process of employer learning. Then, subtracting EquationEquation (6) from wage EquationEquation (3), we obtain

(9) logwi,t=C+α1+α5Si+α2Xi,t+α3Xi,t2+α4SiXi,t+νi,t,(9)

where C=α5C and νi,t=α5μˆi,t1μˆi,0+ϵi,t. This is a standard Mincerian wage equation. Another expansion of EquationEquation (3) is

(10) logwi,t=Ci+α1+α5Si+α2Xi,t+α3Xi,t2+α4SiXi+ϵi,t,(10)

where Ci=α5C+α5μˆi,t1μˆi,0. EquationEquation (10) can be estimated as a fixed effects model.

In EquationEquations (9) and (Equation10), α4 captures at least two factors. One is employer learning. If employers learn about workers’ abilities from their work and reduce the weight of Si through updates of μˆi,0=C+Si over Xi,t, then from EquationEquations (9) and (Equation10),

(11) logwi,tSi,Xi,tSiXi,t=2logwi,tSi,Xi,tSiXi,t=α4<0,(11)

must hold. That is, if the valuation of Si as a signal of ability decreases with Xi,t through employer learning, it drives α4 into the negatives. Mincer (Citation1974) found that the coefficient between schooling and experience, α4, can be negative and posited that this coefficient describes “the apparent convergence of experience profiles” (Mincer, Citation1974, 92–93). However, he did not provide any analytical reasoning for this observation. Since the study by Hansen et al. (Citation1970), the signaling effect has attracted both theoretical and empirical attention. Among the related studies, Farber and Gibbons (Citation1996) established an explicit link between the theoretical and empirical research strands. If employers learn about the innate ability of a specific worker as the worker gains work experience, then the signaling effect of schooling also declines, which results in a negative coefficient of the interaction term between schooling and experience in the Mincerian wage equation.

The other factor that affects α4 is skill complementarity between skills earned by schooling Si and those earned through work experience Xi,t. Complementarity between Si and Xi,t in EquationEquation (1) implies

(12) 2logyi,tSi,Xi,t,μiSiXi,t=α4>0.(12)

That is, α4 increases with the degree of complementarity between Si and Xi,t as employers observe true production technology (1) as long as process (2) implies wi,t/yi,t>0.

In summary, α4 captures the relative impact of the signaling and complementarity effects and increases with the complementarity effect on yi,t relative to the signaling effect on wi,t. For instance, if a schooling track is better tailored toward complementarity with skills acquired through work experience than other tracks, the α4 for graduates of the track would be greater than that for graduates of the other tracks.

3.2. Specifications for the two tracks

Our interest is in whether the degree of skill complementarity between schooling and work experience differs between the general and vocational tracks. To focus on this issue, we consider a wage equation expanded from EquationEquation (9) as follows,

(13) logwi,t=C+β1Sps i+β2Sgt i+β3Svt i+β4Xi,t+β5Xi,t2+β6Sgt i×Xi,t+β7Svt i×Xi,t+νi,t,(13)

where Sps denotes years of general primary and lower-secondary education, Sgt denotes years of general upper-secondary and tertiary education, hereafter the “general track,” and Svt denotes years of vocational upper-secondary and tertiary education, hereafter the “vocational track”. We also consider a fixed effects model specification expanded from EquationEquation (10),

(14) logwi,t=Ci+β1Sps i+β2Sgt i+β3Svt i+β4Xi,t+β5Xi,t2+β6Sgt i×Xi,t+β7Svt i×Xi,t+ϵi,t,(14)

4. Data

For our analysis, we use the Russia Longitudinal Monitoring Survey, which has been administered since 1992 across the Russian Federation.Footnote1 As attrition in each wave is replaced, the survey is an unbalanced panel dataset. Heeringa (Citation1997) reports the survey design and sample attrition. Although the primary goal of the survey is to monitor the process of structural reforms in Russia after the collapse of the USSR, the rich information that the panel data contain has yielded a wide range of research on topics including education, public health, medicine, sociology, and economics in studies such as those by Walker (Citation2006); Stothard et al. (Citation2007); Perlman and Bobak (Citation2008); Wall et al. (Citation2011); Bessudnov et al. (Citation2012); Cherednichenko (Citation2012, Citation2013).Footnote2 Within these concurrent survey data, we use the twelve waves from 1998 to 2009 to ensure data consistency.

Specifically, we used

  • wi,t: Nominal hourly wage in Russian rubles of respondent i in period t.

  • ai,t: Age of respondent i in period t.

  • Si: Total years of schooling of respondent i, such that Si=Sps i+Sgt i+Svt i.

  • Sps i: Years of general primary and lower-secondary education of respondent i.

  • Sgt i: Years of general upper-secondary and tertiary education of respondent i, referred to as the general track.

  • Svt i: Years of vocational upper-secondary and tertiary education of respondent i, referred to as the vocational track.

  • LMXi,t: Years of labor market experience of respondent i in period t, which is ai,tSps i+Sgt i+Svt i.

  • EMPXi,t: Cumulative number of years that respondent i has spent in employment as of period t.

  • UEMPXi,t: Cumulative number of years that respondent i has spent in unemployment as of period t such that LMXi,t=EMPXi,t+UEMPXi,t.

  • Dgi: 1 if respondent i is female and =0 if male.

  • DPostUSSRi: 1 if respondent i graduated from the highest education program after in or after 1991 and =0 otherwise.

  • DSEi,t: 1 if respondent i is employed in a state-owned enterprise in period t and =0 otherwise.

  • DFEi,t: 1 if respondent i is employed in a foreign-owned enterprise in period t and =0 otherwise.

We control for DPostUSSR because we consider the possible peculiarities inherited from the Soviet period and the persistent impact of the reforms implemented after the collapse of the USSR (Brainerd, Citation1998; Flabbi et al., Citation2008; Pastore & Verashchagina, Citation2006). For the same reason, we also control for employment in a state-owned enterprise with the dummy DSE and for employment in a foreign-owned enterprise with the dummy DFE. The descriptive statistics overall and across general and vocational tracks are presented in .

Table 1. Descriptive statistics across tertiary educational backgrounds.

5. Empirical results

5.1. Overview of employer learning

First, we provide an overview of the relationship among wages, education, and labor market experience using total years of schooling Si as the educational background. shows specification (1) based on the standard pooling Mincerian wage regression, which corresponds to EquationEquation (9), and specification (2) according to the Mincerian wage regression of the fixed effects model, which corresponds to EquationEquation (10). The Hausman test indicates that the fixed effects model is preferred to the random effects model to estimate (10).Footnote3 The interaction term between the total years of schooling and labor market experience, Si×LMXi,t, has a significantly negative coefficient in both specifications. These results are consistent with the employer learning hypothesis and the results in the Czech Republic before and after the transition from the communist regime (Münich et al., Citation2005).

Table 2. Employer learning.

5.2. Skill complementarity of the general and vocational tracks

Next, shows the results of applying EquationEquations (13) and (Equation14) as specifications (1) and (2). The Hausman test indicates that the fixed effects model is preferred to the random effects model.Footnote4 The interaction between the general track and labor market experience Sgt×LMX has a significantly negative coefficient in both specifications, as does the interaction between the vocational track and labor market experience Svt×LMX. However, the negativity of the coefficient of the interaction term between the vocational track and labor market experience Svt×LMX is smaller in both specifications, though the confidence intervals overlap. The results do not contradict the inference that the skills that graduates acquire through the vocational track are more complementary to the skills acquired in the workplace relative to the signaling effects than are the skills that graduates acquire through the general track. We further elaborate on the issue below.

Table 3. Skill complementarity of different tracks.

Another finding from is that once fixed effects are controlled for in specification (2), the impact of years of the vocational track (Svt) on wages increases more substantially than that of years of the general track (Sgt). This finding indicates that after controlling for innate ability, skill acquisition through the vocational track may improve productivity more than that through the general track.

Finally, in , labor market experience in EquationEquations (13) and (Equation14) is decomposed into the cumulative number of employed years EMPX and the cumulative number of unemployed years UNEMPX such that LMXi,t=EMPXi,t+UNEMPXi,t for respondent i in period t. The Hausman test indicates that the fixed effects model is preferred to the random effects model.Footnote5

Table 4. Skill complementarity and unemployment depreciation.

In specification (1) corresponding to EquationEquation (13), the interaction between years of the general track and employment experience Sgt×EMPX has a significantly negative coefficient, while the interaction between years of the vocational track and employment experience Svt×EMPX has a significantly positive coefficient. In specification (2) corresponding to EquationEquation (14), Svt×EMPX has an insignificant coefficient, which does not contradict our aforementioned inference that employer learning and skill complementarity work in the opposite directions on α4 in EquationEquation (10).

The signaling effects of the general track mainly appear to act against graduates of the vocational track. Once subsampled into both tracks, the interaction term between the years of general track and employment experience (Sgt×EMPX) does not have a significant coefficient because years of the general track is less informative for comparison within graduates of the general track ( in the appendix). In contrast, within the vocational track, the interaction term between the years of vocational track and employment experience (Svt×EMPX) has a significantly positive coefficient in OLS (specification (1) in in the appendix). However, the coefficient becomes insignificant in the fixed effects model (specification (2) of Table in A2), which indicates that the skill complementarity depends on workers’ innate abilities.

Additionally, once fixed effects are controlled for in specification (2) in , the gap between the returns on general education (Sgt) and vocational education (Svt) shrinks drastically. This finding suggests that skills added by the vocational track to innate abilities, which are controlled for as fixed effects, are substantial.

presents the estimated results of the same specifications in but uses the standardized variables, whose means are 0 and variances are 1, where superscript z denotes the standardized value, except for dummy variables. The Hausman test indicates that the fixed effects model is preferred to the random effects model.Footnote6 We obtain the same qualitative results as those in . Thus, our argument based on is not dependent on scaling the variables.

Table 5. Skill complementarity and unemployment depreciation (standardized).

6. Discussion

Our results indicate that employer learning effects captured by the interaction terms between years of schooling and years of experience are more weakly observed among graduates of the vocational track than among graduates of the general track. As discussed in section 3, one possible reason for this finding is that skills acquired at school and those acquired in the workplace complement each other to improve productivity such that 2yi,t/SiXi,t>0.

Amini and Nivorozhkin (Citation2015) concluded that in the stratified Russian education system, as in Western European systems (Kupfer, Citation2010; von Below et al., Citation2013), students on the vocational track display lower academic achievement than students on the general track. Furthermore, Nikolaev and Chugunov (Citation2012) expressed concerns regarding the state of Russian vocational education, particularly because the once narrowly defined skill building in the Soviet era failed to keep pace with technological changes after the collapse of the USSR (Nikolaev & Chugunov, Citation2012, 45–46). However, our results do not exclude the possibility that Russian vocational education still equips graduates with skills relevant to some industries. One possibility is that vocational education provides graduates with skills that continue to be complementary to the skills to be acquired in the workplace, if less narrowly defined. To explicitly demonstrate the skill complementarity between vocational education and work, we need rich data regarding achievement in vocational education and productivity after graduation, which is beyond the scope of this article. Nonetheless, our results do not rule out this possibility, and thus, this subject is suggested as a topic for future research.

Additionally, education systems are inevitably interdependent with other institutions, notably with labor market institutions, and institutional complementarity leads to historical path dependency (Heyneman, Citation2000). Given this path dependency of interdependent education systems and labor market institutions (Bol & van de Werfhorst, Citation2011), the replacement of the European stratified system with an unstratified system such as that of the US or Japan is unrealistic. The first step in addressing European youth unemployment is to determine whether the vocational education system improves labor market outcomes. Bol and van de Werfhorst (Citation2011) determined that European vocational education provides better employment opportunities through signaling effects. Supporting this viewpoint, we suggest possible complementarity between vocational education and labor market/employment experience.

Recent studies that focus on the positive side of vocational education have emphasized the possibility of improving the academic achievement of students on the vocational track (Heisig & Solga, Citation2015; Prokic-Breuer & Dronkers, Citation2012). However, the specific virtue of the vocational track is that, ideally, it would enable students not only to perform better academically but also to learn skills that are complementary to their work. Our results hint at the possibility that Russian upper-secondary and tertiary vocational schools still equip students with skills that are complementary to work.

As discussed in section 2, the Russian system is unlikely to be the same in specifics but shares essential features with continental Western European systems. Accordingly, our results motivate future research on skill complementarity between vocational education and work experience in other European countries. Finally, Bauer and Haisken DeNew (Citation2001) and Lluis (Citation2005) did not differentiate years of general education and those of vocational education when using the German dataset according to general and vocational tracks. Hence, a comparable analysis of another European giant, e.g., Germany, would deepen our understanding of the interdependence of the European education systems and labor markets institutions.

Acknowledgments

The authors thank the Russia Longitudinal Monitoring Survey, RLMS-HSE (http://www.cpc.unc.edu/projects/rlms-hse), conducted by the National Research University – Higher School of Economics and ZAO Demoscope together with the Carolina Population Center, the University of North Carolina at Chapel Hill, and the Institute of Sociology RAS for making these data available. We are profoundly grateful to the editor in charge, Professor Jorge Miguel Streb, for his insightful suggestions and the three anonymous referees for their informative comments. We also appreciate the helpful comments from Kathryn Dotzel, Michael A. Coon, Pedro Raposo, Joshua Pinkston, and Peter Orazem, and other participants in the SOLE session of the Annual Meetings of the Midwest Economics Association and the Annual North American Meetings of the Regional Science Association International. This work was supported by JSPS KAKENHI Grant Numbers 22K01613 and a research grant from the Japan Center for Economic Research.

Disclosure statement

No potential conflict of interest was reported by the author(s).

Correction Statement

This article has been corrected with minor changes. These changes do not impact the academic content of the article.

Additional information

Funding

The work was supported by the the Japan Society for the Promotion of Science [KAKENHI 22K01613] and the Japan Center for Economic Research.

Notes on contributors

Aigerim Zhangaliyeva

Aigerim Zhangaliyeva received Master of Economics from The University of Tokyo in 2013.

Masaki Nakabayashi

Masaki Nakabayashi is a professor at Institute of Social Science, The University of Tokyo. He received Ph.D. from The University of Tokyo in 1998. Before joining Institute of Social Science, The University of Tokyo, in 2008, he was an assistant professor at Graduate School of Economics, The University of Tokyo, 1998-1999, an associate professor at Department of Economics, Chiba University, 1999-2002, and an associate professor at Graduate School of Economics, Osaka University, 2002-2008. His study ranges from development economics, finance, institutional and organizational economics, economic history, public health, and infectious disease. His works have been published in Economic Modellling, Journal of Policy Modeling, Review of Development Economics, Journal of International Financial Markets, Institutions, and Money, Research in International Business and Finance, The Economic History Review, Social Science Japan Journal, and SSM-Publich Health.

Notes

1 The Russia Longitudinal Monitoring Survey is conducted by the National Research University – Higher School of Economics and ZAO Demoscope together with the Carolina Population Center of the University of North Carolina at Chapel Hill and the Institute of Sociology of the Russian Academy of Sciences. The dataset is open for research use. The instructions for the use of the data and the related data usage policy are available at http://www.cpc.unc.edu/projects/rlms-hse, last accessed on September 16, 2020. For estimations below, we used the plm package for R (https://cran.r-project.org/web/packages/plm/index.html).

2 Information about the publications that have used the dataset is available at https://www.cpc.unc.edu/projects/rlms-hse/publications, last accessed on September 17, 2020.

3 Report of the Hausman test: χ2=12,586, df=8, p value<0.01.

4 Report of the Hausman test: χ2=12,464, df=11, p value<0.01.

5 Report of the Hausman test indicates that χ2=12,177, df=15, p value<0.01.

6 Report of the Hausman test: χ2=12,177, df=15, p value <0.01.

References

  • Allmendinger, J. (1989). Educational systems and labor market outcomes. European Sociological Review, 5(3), 231–23. https://doi.org/10.1093/oxfordjournals.esr.a036524
  • Altonji, J. G., & Pierret, C. R. (2001). Employer learning and statistical discrimination. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 116(1), 313–350. https://doi.org/10.1162/003355301556329
  • Amini, C., & Nivorozhkin, E. (2015). The urban–rural divide in educational outcomes: Evidence from Russia. International Journal of Educational Development, 44, 118–133. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ijedudev.2015.07.006
  • Bannatyne, M. W. M., & Hall, R. A. (1998). Technology and vocational educational reform in the Russian Federation. Journal of Technology Studies, 24(2), 31–37. https://doi.org/10.21061/jots.v24i2.a.4
  • Bartels, L. M. (2002). Beyond the running tally: Partisan bias in political perceptions. Political Behavior, 24(2), 117–150. https://doi.org/10.1023/A:1021226224601
  • Bauer, T. K., & Haisken DeNew, J. P. (2001). Employer learning and the returns to schooling. Labour Economics, 8(2), 161–180. https://doi.org/10.1016/S0927-53710100026-4
  • Bessudnov, A., McKee, M., & Stuckler, D. (2012). Inequalities in male mortality by occupational class, perceived status and education in Russia, 1994–2006. European Journal of Public Health, 22(3), 332–337. https://doi.org/10.1093/eurpub/ckr130
  • Biewen, M., & Thiele, M. (2020). Early tracking, academic vs. vocational training, and the value of ‘second-chance’ options. Labour Economics, 66, 101900. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.labeco.2020.101900
  • Blázquez, M., Herrarte, A., & Sáez, F. (2019). Training and job search assistance programmes in Spain: The case of long-term unemployed. Journal of Policy Modeling, 41(2), 316–335. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jpolmod.2019.03.004
  • Bol, T., & van de Werfhorst, H. G. (2011). Signals and closure by degrees: The education effect across 15 European countries. Research in Social Stratification and Mobility, 29(1), 119–132. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.rssm.2010.12.002
  • Brainerd, E. (1998). Winners and losers in Russia’s economic transition. The American Economic Review, 88(5), 1094–1116. https://www.jstor.org/stable/116862
  • Cherednichenko, G. A. (2012). The educational and professional trajectories of working young people. Russian Education and Society, 54(11), 34–52. https://doi.org/10.2753/RES1060-9393541103
  • Cherednichenko, G. A. (2013). The professional trajectories and accumulation of educational resources of young people after acquiring a secondary education. Russian Education and Society, 55(1), 3–36. https://doi.org/10.2753/RES1060-9393550101
  • Choi, S. J., Chul Jeong, J., & Nam Kim, S. (2019). Impact of vocational education and training on adult skills and employment: An applied multilevel analysis. International Journal of Educational Development, 66, 129–138. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ijedudev.2018.09.007
  • DiPrete, T. A., Bol, T., Ciocca Eller, C., & van de Werfhorst, H. G. (2017). School-to-work linkages in the United States, Germany, and France. American Journal of Sociology, 122(6), 1869–1938. https://doi.org/10.1086/691327
  • The European Centre for the Development of Vocational Training, ed. 2004a. Towards a history of vocational education and training (vet) in Europe in a comparative perspective: Proceedings of the First International Conference October 2002, Florence, Volume I The Rise of National VET Systems in a Comparative Perspective. Luxembourg:Office for Official Publications of the European Communities. http://www.cedefop.europa.eu/files/5153_1_en.pdf
  • The European Centre for the Development of Vocational Training, ed. 2004b. Towards a history of Vocational Education and Training (VET) in Europe in a comparative perspective: Proceedings of the First International Conference October 2002, Florence, Volume II The Development of VET in the Context of the Construction of the EC/EU and the Role of Cedefop. Luxembourg: Office for Official Publications of the European Communities. http://www.cedefop.europa.eu/files/5153_2_en.pdf
  • Farber, H. S., & Gibbons, R. (1996). Learning and wage dynamics. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 111(4), 1007–1047. https://doi.org/10.2307/2946706
  • Flabbi, L., Paternostro, S., & Tiongson, E. R. (2008). Returns to education in the economic transition: A systematic assessment using comparable data. Economics of Education Review, 27(6), 724–740. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.econedurev.2007.09.011
  • Forster, A. G., & Bol, T. (2018). Vocational education and employment over the life course using a new measure of occupational specificity. Social Science Research, 70, 176–197. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ssresearch.2017.11.004
  • Gerber, T. P. (2003). Loosening links? School-to-work transitions and institutional change in Russia since 1970. Social Forces, 82(1), 241–276. https://doi.org/10.1353/sof.2003.0085
  • Gerber, A., & Green, D. (1999). Misperception about perceptual bias. Annual Review of Political Science, 2(1), 189–210. https://doi.org/10.1146/annurev.polisci.2.1.189
  • Gerber, T. P., & Hout, M. (1995). Educational stratification in Russia during the Soviet period. American Journal of Sociology, 101(3), 611–660. https://doi.org/10.1086/230755
  • Glaesser, J., & Cooper, B. (2011). Selectivity and flexibility in the German secondary school system: A configurational analysis of recent data from the German Socio-Economic Panel. European Sociological Review, 27(5), 570–585. https://doi.org/10.1093/esr/jcq026
  • Habermalz, S. (2006). More detail on the pattern of returns to educational signals. Southern Economic Journal, 73(1), 125–135. https://doi.org/10.1002/j.2325-8012.2006.tb00761.x
  • Hall, C. (2016). Does more general education reduce the risk of future unemployment? Evidence from an expansion of vocational upper secondary education. Economics of Education Review, 52, 251–271. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.econedurev.2016.03.005
  • Han, S. W. (2016). National education systems and gender gaps in STEM occupational expectations. International Journal of Educational Development, 49, 175–187. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ijedudev.2016.03.004
  • Hansen, W. L., Weisbrod, B. A., & William, T. S. (1970). Schooling and earnings of low achievers. The American Economic Review, 60(3), 409–418. https://www.jstor.org/stable/1817990
  • Heckman, J. J., Lochner, L. J., and Todd, P. E. (2006). Earnings functions, rates of return and treatment effects: The Mincer equation and beyond. In E. Hanushek & F. Welch (Eds.), Handbook of the Economics of Education (Vol. 1, pp. 307–458). Elsevier. https://doi.org/10.1016/S1574-0692(06)01007-5
  • Heckman, J. J., Lochner, L. J., & Todd, P. E. (2008). Earnings functions and rates of return. Journal of Human Capital, 2(1), 1–31. https://doi.org/10.1086/587037
  • Heeringa, S. G. (1997). Russia Longitudinal Monitoring Survey (RLMS): Sample attrition, replenishment, and weighting in rounds V–VII.
  • Heisig, J. P., & Solga, H. (2015). Secondary education systems and the general skills of less- and intermediate-educated adults: A comparison of 18 countries. Sociology of Education, 88(3), 202–225. https://doi.org/10.1177/0038040715588603
  • Heyneman, S. P. (1997). Education and social stability in Russia: An essay. Compare: A Journal of Comparative & International Education, 27(1), 5–18. https://doi.org/10.1080/0305792970270102
  • Heyneman, S. P. (1998). The transition from party/state to open democracy: The role of education. International Journal of Educational Development, 18(1), 21–40. https://doi.org/10.1016/S0738-05939700039-4
  • Heyneman, S. P. (2000). From the party/state to multiethnic democracy: Education and social cohesion in Europe and Central Asia. Educational Evaluation and Policy Analysis, 22(2), 173–191. https://doi.org/10.3102/01623737022002173
  • Heywood, J. S. (1994). How widespread are sheepskin returns to education in the U.S? Economics of Education Review, 13(3), 227–234. https://doi.org/10.1016/0272-77579490010-8
  • Holmes, L. E. (1973). Bolshevik utilitarianism and educational experimentalism: Party attitudes and soviet educational practice, 1917–1931. History of Education Quarterly, 13(4), 347–365. https://doi.org/10.2307/367381
  • Kerckhoff, A. C. (2001). Education and social stratification processes in comparative perspective. Sociology of Education, 74(Extra Issue), 3–18. https://doi.org/10.2307/2673250
  • Kotásek, J. (1996). Structure and organisation of secondary education in Central and Eastern Europe. European Journal of Education, 31(1), 25–42. https://www.jstor.org/stable/1503555
  • Kupfer, A. (2010). The socio-political significance of changes to the vocational education system in Germany. British Journal of Sociology of Education, 31(1), 85–97. https://doi.org/10.1080/01425690903385519
  • Lange, F. (2007). The speed of employer learning. Journal of Labor Economics, 25(1), 1–35. https://doi.org/10.1086/508730
  • Lluis, S. (2005). The role of comparative advantage and learning in wage dynamics and intrafirm mobility: Evidence from Germany. Journal of Labor Economics, 23(4), 725–767. https://doi.org/10.1086/491607
  • Magsumov, T. A. (2018). Apprenticeship in secondary vocational schools during the economic modernization in late imperial Russia. Part 1. European Journal of Contemporary Education, 7(4), 918–926. http://dx.doi.org/10.13187/ejced.2018.4.918
  • Magsumov, T. A. (2019). Apprenticeship in secondary vocational schools during the economic modernization in late imperial Russia. Part 2. European Journal of Contemporary Education, 8(1), 215–221. https://doi.org/10.13187/ejced.2019.1.215
  • Marques, I., Remington, T., & Bazavliuk, V. (2020). Encouraging skill development: Evidence from public-private partnerships in education in Russia’s regions. European Journal of Political Economy, 63, 101888. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ejpoleco.2020.101888
  • Meyser, J. (2004). The production school concept as Europe’s first didactically vocational training model. Office for Official Publications of the European Communities.
  • Mijs, J. J. B. (2016). Stratified failure: Educational stratification and students’ attributions of their mathematics performance in 24 countries. Sociology of Education, 89(2), 137–153. https://doi.org/10.1177/0038040716636434
  • Mincer, J. (1974). Schooling, Experience, and Earnings. National Bureau of Economic Research.
  • Münich, D., Svejnar, J., & Terrell, K. (2005). Returns to human capital under the communist wage grid and during the transition to a market economy. The Review of Economics and Statistics, 87(1), 100–123. https://doi.org/10.1162/0034653053327559
  • Murillo, I. P., Rahona-López, M., & Del Mar Salinas-Jiménez, M. (2012). Effects of educational mismatch on private returns to education: An analysis of the Spanish case (1995–2006). Journal of Policy Modeling, 34(5), 646–659. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jpolmod.2011.07.012
  • Nikolaev, D., & Chugunov, D. (2012). The education system in the Russian federation: Education brief 2012. The World Bank. https://openknowledge.worldbank.org/handle/10986/6012
  • Okenfuss, M. J. (1973). Technical training in Russia under Peter the Great. History of Education Quarterly, 13(4), 325–345. https://doi.org/10.2307/367380
  • Olfindo, R. (2018). Diploma as signal? Estimating sheepskin effects in the Philippines. International Journal of Educational Development, 60, 113–119. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ijedudev.2017.11.001
  • Pastore, F., & Verashchagina, A. (2006). Private returns to human capital over transition: A case study of Belarus. Economics of Education Review, 25(1), 91–107. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.econedurev.2004.11.003
  • Perlman, F., & Bobak, M. (2008). Socioeconomic and behavioral determinants of mortality in posttransition Russia: A Prospective population study. Annals of Epidemiology, 18(2), 92–100. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.annepidem.2007.07.093
  • Pfeffer, F. T. (2008). Persistent inequality in educational attainment and its institutional context. European Sociological Review, 24(5), 543–565. https://doi.org/10.1093/esr/jcn026
  • Pinkston, J. C. (2006). A test of screening discrimination with employer learning. Industrial and Labor Relations Review, 59(2), 267–284. https://doi.org/10.1177/001979390605900205
  • Popescu, M. E., & Roman, M. (2018). Vocational training and employability: Evaluation evidence from Romania. Evaluation and Program Planning, 67, 38–46. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.evalprogplan.2017.11.001
  • Powell, J. J. W., Bernhard, N., & Graf, L. (2012). The emergent European model in skill formation: Comparing higher education and vocational training in the Bologna and Copenhagen processes. Sociology of Education, 85(3), 240–258. https://doi.org/10.1177/0038040711427313
  • Prokic-Breuer, T., & Dronkers, J. (2012). The high performance of Dutch and Flemish 15-year-old native pupils: Explaining country differences in math scores between highly stratified educational systems. Educational Research & Evaluation, 18(8), 749–777. https://doi.org/10.1080/13803611.2012.727359
  • Roth, T. (2018). The influence of parents’ social capital on their children’s transition to vocational training in Germany. Social Networks, 55, 74–85. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.socnet.2018.05.006
  • Schönberg, U. (2007). Testing for asymmetric employer learning. Journal of Labor Economics, 25(4), 651–691. https://doi.org/10.1086/522905
  • Solga, H., & Konietzka, D. (1999). Occupational matching and social stratification: Theoretical insights and empirical observations Taken from a German-German comparison. European Sociological Review, 15(1), 25–47. https://doi.org/10.1093/oxfordjournals.esr.a018253
  • Spence, M. (1973). Job market signaling. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 87(3), 355–374. https://doi.org/10.2307/1882010
  • Stanziani, A. (2009a). The traveling Panopticon: Labor institutions and labor practices in Russia and Britain in the eighteenth and nineteenth centuries. Comparative Studies in Society and History, 51(4), 715–741. https://doi.org/10.1017/S0010417509990119
  • Stanziani, A. (2009b). The legal status of labour from the seventeenth to the nineteenth century: Russia in a comparative European perspective. International Review of Social History, 54(3), 359–389. https://doi.org/10.1017/S0020859009990307
  • Stothard, B., Romanova, O., & Ivanova, L. (2007). Recent developments in HIV/AIDS prevention for Russian adolescents. Sex Education, 7(2), 175–189. https://doi.org/10.1080/14681810701264540
  • Temple, J. (2002). Growth effects of education and social capital in the OECD countries. Historical Social Research/Historische Sozialforschung, 27(4 (102), 5–46. https://doi.org/10.12759/hsr.27.2002.4.5-46
  • van der Meer, P. H. (2011). Educational credentials and external effects: A test for the Netherlands. Research in Social Stratification and Mobility, 29(1), 107–118. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.rssm.2010.12.003
  • van de Werfhorst, H. G. (2011). Skill and education effects on earnings in 18 Countries: The role of national educational institutions. Social Science Research, 40(4), 1078–1090. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ssresearch.2011.03.004
  • von Below, S., Powell, J. J. W., & Roberts, L. W. (2013). Educational systems and rising inequality: Eastern Germany after unification. Sociology of Education, 86(4), 362–375. https://doi.org/10.1177/0038040713496585
  • Waldman, M. (1984). Job assignments, signalling, and efficiency. The RAND Journal of Economics, 15(2), 255–267. https://doi.org/10.2307/2555679
  • Waldman, M., Gibbons, R., & Roberts, J. (2013). 13. Theory and Evidence in Internal Labor Markets. Princeton University Press. https://doi.org/10.1515/9781400845354-015
  • Walker, C. (2006). Managing vocational education and the youth labour market in post-Soviet Russia. The International Journal of Human Resource Management, 17(8), 1426–1440. https://doi.org/10.1080/09585190600804473
  • Wallenborn, M. (2010). Vocational education and training and human capital development: Current practice and future options. European Journal of Education, 45(2), 181–198. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1465-3435.2010.01424.x
  • Wall, M., Schmidt, E., Sarang, A., Atun, R., & Renton, A. (2011). Sex, drugs and economic behaviour in Russia: A study of socio- economic characteristics of high risk populations. International Journal of Drug Policy, 22(2), 133–139. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.drugpo.2010.10.001
  • Wang, J., & Li, B. (2020). Does employer learning with statistical discrimination exist in China? Evidence from Chinese micro survey data. International Review of Economics & Finance, 69, 319–333. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.iref.2020.05.021
  • Wiemann, G. (2004). Lehrgangsausbildung: A European prototype of a universal industry-based training method. Office for Official Publications of the European Communities. http://www.cedefop.europa.eu/files/5153_1_en.pdf
  • Witte, J. C., & Kalleberg, A. L. (1995). Matching training and jobs: The fit between vocational education and employment in the German labour market. European Sociological Review, 11(3), 293–317. https://doi.org/10.1093/oxfordjournals.esr.a036365
  • Zajda, J. (2003). Educational reform and transformation in Russia. European Education, 35(1), 58–88. https://doi.org/10.2753/EUE1056-4934350158
  • Zilic, I. (2018). General versus vocational education: Lessons from a quasi- experiment in Croatia. Economics of Education Review, 62, 1–11. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.econedurev.2017.10.009

 

A.1 Belief updates by employers

Motivated by Bartels (2002), we consider a Bayesian update model

(A1) μˆi,t=1σμˆi,t121σμˆi,t12+1σξ2μˆi,t1+1σξ21σμˆi,t12+1σξ2ri,t,(A1)

where the prior belief in period t1 and the new information in period t are weighted by their precision evaluated by the reciprocal of their variances. Following Bartels (2002), the posterior precision in period t, 1/σμˆi,t2, given by the prior precision and the precision of the new information is presented as

(A2) 1σμˆi,t2=1σμˆi,t12+1σξ2,(A2)

which leads to the update of the estimated ability in period t=1

(A3) μˆt,1=1σω21σω2+1σξ2μˆi,0+1σξ21σω2+1σξ2ri,1,(A3)

since

(A4) 1σμˆi,12=1σω2+1σξ2.(A4)

From period t=2 onward, the new evidence follows the same process. Then, the assumption that σξ2=σω2 yields EquationEquation (8).

A.2 Supplementary result

present the results of the same specifications as in for each subsample of the general and vocational tracks. Unsurprisingly, the interaction term between general upper-secondary and tertiary education and employment experience (Sgt×EMPX) does not have a significant coefficient in either the OLS (1) or fixed effects model (2) in . This is because the general track served as a signal of ability primarily against graduates of the vocational track. Once subsampled as graduates of the general track, the signal has little impact.

Table A1. Skill complementarity and unemployment depreciation: General upper-secondary and tertiary education.

Table A2. Skill complementarity and unemployment depreciation: Vocational upper-secondary and tertiary education.

Additionally, the interaction term between years of the vocational track and employment experience (Svt×EMPX) has a significantly positive coefficient in the OLS specification. This result indicates that years of vocational track education are valued as complements of employment experience and further indicates that Russian vocational education provides graduates with skills that are complementary to work experience rather than just providing signals against graduates of the general track.

split the sample into the first half of the period, 1994–2001, and the second half of the period, 2002–2009. The interaction term between the general track and employment experience (Sgt×EMPX) does not have a significant coefficient in either subsample, which indicates that employer learning effects are hardly observed in the short term. For the second half period, the interaction term between the vocational track and employment experience (Svt×EMPX) has a significantly positive coefficient, which indicates skill complementarity, for the second half period (), but it does not for the first half period (). Thus, the skill complementarity effects of the vocational track are not warranted in the short term.

Table A3. Skill complementarity of different tracks: 1994–2001.

Table A4. Skill complementarity of different tracks: 2002–2009.