2,936
Views
1
CrossRef citations to date
0
Altmetric
FINANCIAL ECONOMICS

The expected sharpe ratio of efficient portfolios under estimation errors

ORCID Icon & | (Reviewing editor)
Article: 1943910 | Received 17 Oct 2020, Accepted 10 Jun 2021, Published online: 19 Jul 2021

Abstract

This paper aims to develop a feasible estimator of the Sharpe ratio that the investor would expect from estimated efficient portfolios. Based on the analytical expression of the expected Sharpe ratio, we construct an estimator that captures all the errors involved in the estimated efficient portfolios. We conduct a simulation study and find that our estimator delivers the lowest mean square error with comparison to existing estimators. Our result is robust to sample size, to number of assets and to non-normality. It works well, particularly, with short sample sizes. The superior performance of the proposed estimator is confirmed through empirical analysis. The ex-ante method developed in this work allows the investor to assess the value of efficient portfolios before investing capital.

Public interest statement

Investors in the stock market often seek efficient portfolios with higher returns and lower risks. A prominent portfolio choice framework that meets these requirements is the mean-variance model established by Markowitz in Citation1952. This model promises to investors to hold efficient portfolios that offer maximum performance. The practical implementation of this model requires the estimation of the optimal portfolio weights invested in the risky assets. However, these estimated weights suffer from estimation errors, which affect portfolio performance. The aim of this article is to quantify the performance that we expect from estimated efficient portfolios using a popular performance measure: the Sharpe ratio. We propose an improved method that helps the investor to assess the value of efficient portfolios before investing capital.

1. Introduction

Since the seminal work of Markowitz (Citation1952, Citation1959), the mean-variance analysis has become the most dominant approach used in practice.Footnote1 Investors often use the mean-variance model to build their portfolios and evaluate the performance of their investments based on the Sharpe ratio,Footnote2 despite the existence of several alternatives to this measure.

The Sharpe ratio, introduced by Sharpe (Citation1966, Citation1994), measures the expected excess return per unit of risk. Many researchers find that alternative performance measures generate identical rank ordering as the Sharpe ratio, despite the significant deviations from the normal distribution (e.g., see Eling and Schuhmacher (Citation2007), Eling (Citation2008), and Auer (Citation2015)). Thus, investors can use simple metrics such as the Sharpe ratio instead of more complex ones.

This performance metric is derived under the mean-variance framework that promises to investors to hold efficient portfolios that offer the maximum Sharpe ratio. To achieve this performance, mean-variance analysis assumes that the investor knows, with certainty, the parameters of the portfolio selection model namely the vector of expected returns on individual assets and the corresponding covariance matrix. However, in the real world, investors need to estimate these parameters using samples of historical return data. Replacing true parameters with estimated parameters often generates errors. These estimation errors negatively affect the performance of efficient portfolios (e.g., see DeMiguel et al. (Citation2009), Tu and Zhou (Citation2011), and Kan et al. (Citation2016)). Therefore, the Sharpe ratio promised by portfolio theory is never achieved in practice.

A natural question arises: what is the Sharpe ratio the investor would expect from estimated efficient portfolios? To answer this question, previous researches rely on ex-post approach to estimate the Sharpe ratio (e.g., see DeMiguel et al. (Citation2009), Chen and Yuan (Citation2016), and Shi et al. (Citation2020)). With this method, portfolio performance is measured after an investment decision has been made. Thus, the portfolio manager is not able to know if he made the right decision only after the end of the investment period. While this method is helpful in quantifying the ex-post results, we need an ex-ant method to assess the out-of-sample Sharpe ratio that can help the investor at the time of investment.

Relatively few studies have investigated the problem from this perspective. For example, Kourtis (Citation2016) evaluates the out-of-sample performance of estimated efficient portfolios using an estimator based on analytical expressions of the expected squared Sharpe ratio and assuming that the covariance matrix is known by the investor. Nevertheless, the squared Sharpe ratio is not the appropriate measure of performance in this context since it is not founded theoretically as a performance measure and not compatible with the mean-variance framework. In addition, errors on the covariance matrix can have a large impact on portfolio performance, especially when the estimation length is small compared to the number of assets, as Kan and Zhou (Citation2007), Ledoit and Wolf (Citation2012) show. Thus, ignoring these errors when constructing the estimator of the Sharpe ratio of an estimated efficient portfolio leads to inaccurate results.

Recently, Paulsen and Söhl (Citation2020) derived an unbiased estimator adjusting for both sources of bias: noise fit and estimation error. The authors show how to use their adjusted Sharpe ratio as a model selection criterion analogously to the Akaike Information Criterion. However, their result also depends on knowledge of the true covariance matrix of the efficient portfolio. Furthermore, to compute the proposed estimator, the authors utilize the same sample return data used to construct the efficient portfolio. Practically, portfolios are constructed with short samples of historical returns. Although their estimator is unbiased, it is not clear how it behaves for small sample sizes.

The aim of this paper is to derive a feasible estimator of the Sharpe ratio we expect from estimated efficient portfolios. Based on the analytical expression of the expected Sharpe ratio, we construct an estimator that captures all the errors involved in the estimated efficient portfolios and improves upon existing estimators under quadratic loss. It works well, particularly, for short sample lengths.

The remainder of the paper is organized as follows: Section 2 outlines the portfolio choice problem. Section 3 provides an analytical expression of the expected Sharpe ratio of estimated mean-variance portfolios. Section 4 develops a method to assess the Sharpe ratio of estimated efficient portfolios. We conduct a simulation study and empirical analysis in Section 5 and 6, respectively, to evaluate the performance of the suggested estimator by comparison to existing competitors. Section 7 concludes. The proofs are moved to the Appendix.

2. The portfolio choice problem

In this section, we describe the portfolio choice problem for a mean-variance investor who chooses an optimal portfolio among N risky assets and a risk-free asset.

2.1. Under parameter certainty

Denote the returns of the N risky assets and the riskless asset at time t by Rt and Rtf, respectively. Let then rt=RtRtf be the vector of excess returns, where is an N×1 vector of ones. We assume that rt is independent and follows a multivariate normal distribution with mean μ and covariance matrix Σ. Under the mean-variance framework, the objective of the investor is to maximize the following utility function:

(1) Uw=wμγ2wΣw,(1)

where w is the vector of weights of the N risky assets and γ is the investor’s relative risk aversion. wμ and wΣw are the portfolio mean excess return and variance, respectively. Under parameter certainty, i.e., μ and Σ are known to the investor, it is easy to show that the optimal weights allocated to the risky assets are

(2) w=Σ1μγ,(2)

and thus 1w is invested in the risk-free asset.Footnote3 This optimal portfolio delivers the highest Sharpe ratio

(3) θ=μΣ1μ(3)

2.2. Under parameter uncertainty

In reality, μ and Σ are unknown to investors and need to be estimated. To compute the portfolio weights, the investor is constrained to estimate the expected returns of risky assets, the variances and covariances from a set of T periods of historical return data.

The sample estimates of the vector of expected returns μ and covariance Σ matrix are given, respectively, by

(4) μˆ=1Tt=1T t(4)
(5) Σˆ=1Tt=1Trtμˆrtμˆ(5)

The simplest way to estimate w is to replace μ and Σ in (2) by μˆ and Σˆ to obtain wˆ=1γΣˆ1μˆ, which is the maximum likelihood estimator of w. Then, the Sharpe ratio of the estimated efficient portfolio is

(6) Sˆ=wˆμwˆΣwˆ.(6)

We notice from Equationequation (6) that the Sharpe ratio of estimated efficient portfolios is a nonlinear function of a random variable, wˆ, which itself depends on the precision degree of parameter estimation. Due to estimation errors in wˆ, this will generally be lower than θ. With the stochastic representation of Sˆ, we can obtain the expression of the expected Sharpe ratio.

3. The expected Sharpe ratio

In this section, we, first, derive analytical formula of the expected Sharpe ratio, i.e., the average out-of-sample performance the investor would realize if he estimates his efficient portfolio by a set of historical return data. Second, we study its accuracy. Finally, we analyze the determinants and the properties of this analytical formula of the expected Sharpe ratio.

3.1. Analytical expression

The following proposition derives an approximation of the expected Sharpe ratio that delivers an efficient portfolio where the elements of the vector of expected returns and the covariance matrix used to compute this portfolio are estimated from historical data.

Proposition 1 For T>N+4, the expected Sharpe ratio for the estimated efficient portfolios can be expressed as follows:

(7) ESˆ:=TN1TN4TN2T2NTθ2+1θ(7)

3.2. Accuracy of the analytical expression

The previous formula of the expected Sharpe ratio is derived under a Taylor series expansion and assuming independent and identically normally distributed returns. To study the accuracy of this analytical expression and the validity of normality assumption on return data, we conduct a simulation experiment.

The simulation design attributes to the covariance matrix a Toeplitz structure, i.e., Σ=Σi,j=δij for i,j=1,,N. The vector of expected returns is proportional to a constant, i.e., μ=kl We set N=10,30,40 and 50. For each number of assets, N, we compute the analytical expression of the expected Sharpe ratio, ESˆ using four different estimation lengths (T=120,240,360 and 480). To study its accuracy, we compare it to the true values ζ and ξ computed using simulated returns generated from normal and student distributions with 8 degrees of freedom, respectively. Setting δ=0.5 and k=0.05, the results from this experiment are reported in .

Table 1. Accuracy of the approximation of the expected Sharpe ratio

First, comparing the true values of the expected Sharpe ratio under different distribution assumptions, we find that they are close to each other since the difference is too small. This suggests that the assumption of normality is irrelevant in evaluating portfolio performance in terms of the expected Sharpe ratio for a mean-variance investor. Tu and Zhou (Citation2004) find similar result for the certainty-equivalent performance measure.

Second, comparing the analytical formula of the expected Sharpe ratio to the true values, we can see that the error is relatively small for the different number of assets and decreases with the sample length. As a result, we can conclude that the analytical formula is an accurate approximation of the expected Sharpe ratio.

3.3. Determinants and properties

EquationEquation (7) in proposition one affirms, first, that the expected Sharpe ratio is a function of three determinants: the number of assets N, the sample size, T, and the maximum Sharpe ratio θ. It increases with the estimation length and the maximum Sharpe ratio and decreases with the number of assets. Intuitively, as the estimation length increases, μˆ and Σˆ become more accurate estimators of μ and Σ, so the out of sample Sharpe ratio increases. On the other hand, the greater the number of assets, the greater the number of elements of μ and Σ that must be estimated. This leads to more errors in estimating the portfolio weights, which drives down the performance. Furthermore, the higher the maximum Sharpe ratio (i.e., the more the portfolios are diversified), the larger the expected Sharpe ratio of estimated portfolios is.

Second, for a given number of assets, when T goes to infinity, we note that the expected Sharpe ratio converges to its maximum value. This implies that the investor needs a huge quantity of historical data to estimate parameters with precision and thus reach the maximum performance as predicted by the theory. While in practice he possesses a limited quantity of historical information, attaining such performance remains a difficult task.

4. Estimating the Sharpe ratio

The analytical formula of the expected Sharpe ratio developed in the previous section depends on an unknown parameter, θ2, which makes it unfeasible tool to compute the out-of-sample performance of estimated efficient portfolios. In this section, we show how to construct a feasible estimator. This is achieved by replacing θ2 by an improved estimator.

4.1. Estimation design

Technically, we estimate, first, θ2 based on the available data. Then, we calculate the estimated expected Sharpe ratio of the efficient portfolio using the expression (7) in proposition one by replacing θ2 by its estimate. A natural estimator of θ2 is its sample counterpart,

(8) θˆ2=μˆΣˆ1μˆ.(8)

However, this estimator can be heavily biased when the sample length, T, is small (see, for instance, Kan and Zhou (Citation2007)); which is a common practical situation that the investor faces. Indeed, the investor has access to a limited quantity of historical information available for the estimation. To alleviate the problem, we can replace θ2 by its unbiased estimator (see expression (49) of Kan and Zhou (Citation2007))

(9) θˆu2=TN2θˆ2NT.(9)

Despite the fact that this is an accurate estimator of θ2 for large sample size, it can take negative values for short sample size. Thus, it is also an undesirable estimator of θ2.

4.2. Adjusted estimator

For our application, we use an adjusted estimator of θ2.

(10) θ˜2=maxTN2θˆ2NT,2TN2TN+2θˆ2,(10)

where T>N+2 and θˆ2 is given by Equationequation (8). This estimator is due to the fact that Tθˆ2 follows a non-central F-distribution with N and TN degrees of freedom and a non-centrality parameter Tθ2. We express θ˜2 as a function of the unbiased estimator θˆu2 to get:

(11) θ˜2=maxθˆu2,2Tθˆu2+NTN+2.(11)

From the last equation, we see that if θˆu2 is large (i.e., θˆu22T) then θ˜2 is equal to θˆu2 and behaves exactly like the unbiased estimator. On the other hand, if θˆu2 is small (i.e., θˆu2<2T) then θ˜2 is greater than θˆu2. Although in this case the estimator presents some bias, it has some desirable features. First, it dominates the unbiased estimator in terms of minimizing the quadratic loss (see Theorem 3.1 of Kubokawa et al. (Citation1993)). Second, this dominance persists even if the estimator is computed with a short estimation length. The reason is that the condition of small θˆu2 is most likely to be verified when T is short. Third, with this design we prevent our estimator from taking negative values.

Substituting θ˜2 for θ2 in (7), we can gauge the Sharpe ratio of estimated efficient portfolios. For T>N+4, the resulting estimator is as follows:

(12) Sˉ=TN1TN4TN2T2NTθ˜2+1θ˜.(12)

5. Simulation study

In this section, we examine and compare the performance of our estimator with that of alternative estimators. We begin with a presentation of the simulation set-up. Then, we provide a description of alternative competitors. Finally, we report and discuss our simulation results.

5.1. Set-up

We use the same design for the covariance matrix, Σ, and the vector of expected returns, μ, as in section 3. We perform two simulation experiments.

The first simulation aims to study the behavior of the mean square error (MSE) of our estimator and the competitor estimators as a function of the estimation length. For N=10, we simulate a random sample of returns of length T (T=60,120,,600), generated from a multivariate normal distribution NNμ,Σ. We then compute the estimators of the out of sample Sharpe ratio for the specified sample length. We iterate the design 5000 times. From the iterations, we compute the MSE for each sample length.

The goal of the second simulation is to examine the behavior of the MSE as a function of the number of assets. We set T=240. For each number of assets N (N=10,20,30,40,50), we draw a random sample of returns from a multivariate normal distribution. Then, we compute the estimators. We repeat the simulation 5000 times and we get the MSE delivered by our estimator and the alternative estimators for each number of assets. We repeat these two simulation experiences using data generated by a heavy-tailed distribution.

5.2. Competitors

We consider two competitors to our proposed estimator. The first one is derived by Kourtis (Citation2016) used to assess the value of the expected squared Sharpe ratio. The author derives two approximations of the squared Sharpe ratio estimator using first order and second-order Taylor series expansions. We use the second-order approximation as it is more precise by construction. It is defined by the following expression:

(13) ζˉ2=θˉ2N1θˉ2N+Tθˉ22N1Tθˉ4(N+Tθˉ2)3.(13)
(14) Whereθˉ2=maxθNT,2N+2θ(14)
(15) andθ=μˆΣ1μˆ(15)

To make a fair comparison between our estimator and the Kourtis estimator, we use the formula of the Sharpe ratio estimator, ζˉ, instead of the squared Sharpe ratio estimator. Moreover, we replace the unknown covariance matrix in Equationequation (15) by its sample counterpart in order to ensure a practical estimation framework.

The second competitor is an unbiased estimator proposed by Paulsen and Söhl (Citation2020) and has the following expression:

(16) τ=θNTθ(16)

Where θ is given by Equationequation (15). As in the Kourtis estimator case, we replace the unknown covariance matrix by its sample counterpart.

5.3. Results

In and , we present the simulation results for normally distributed data. presents the global behavior of the estimators for different estimation lengths T. While shows the properties of the studied estimators for a fixed portfolio dimension (N=10), depicts the general behavior for different dimensions.

To start with the results of , we notice that the MSE is a decreasing function of the estimation length. Clearly, we see our proposed estimator shows the best performance since it delivers the lowest MSE among all others regardless of the sample size used to construct it. Our method works well especially with small sample estimation lengths. To give a specific example, with T=60, our estimator error is 0.011, which is approximately three times less than the Kourtis estimator error (0.031) and more than four times less than the Paulsen and Söhl estimator error (0.049).

Figure 1. MSE of the expected Sharpe ratio estimators as a function of the estimation length

Note: This figure plots the MSE of our estimator of the expected Sharpe ratio derived in Equationequation (12), the Kourtis estimator and the Paulsen and Söhl estimator as a function of the estimation length T. The number of assets N is equal to 10. For each sample of returns of length T, simulated from a multivariate normal distribution, we compute the estimators of the out of sample Sharpe ratio. Then, we iterate the design 5000 times to compute the MSE.
Figure 1. MSE of the expected Sharpe ratio estimators as a function of the estimation length

From , we can see that the MSEs of the estimators increase with the number of assets. The Paulsen and Söhl estimator has the worst performance since it involves much more errors as the portfolio dimension becomes larger. The Kourtis estimator behaves much better for small portfolio dimensions. However, the errors grow up rapidly for large portfolio dimensions and reach similar badly results as in the case of the Paulsen and Söhl estimator. Our estimator outperforms all the competitors since it has the lowest MSE regardless the size of the portfolio. Furthermore, we notice that our proposed estimator is less sensitive to the dimension of the portfolio since the MSE evolves slowly with high number of assets.

Figure 2. MSE of the expected Sharpe ratio estimators as a function of the portfolio dimension

Note: This figure plots the MSE of our estimator of the expected Sharpe ratio derived in Equationequation (12), the Kourtis estimator and the Paulsen and Söhl estimator as a function of the number of assets N. The estimation length T is equal to 240. For each number of assets N, we simulate a sample of returns of length T from a multivariate normal distribution. Then, we compute the estimators of the out of sample Sharpe ratio. We iterate the design 5000 times to compute the MSE.
Figure 2. MSE of the expected Sharpe ratio estimators as a function of the portfolio dimension

In and , we present the results for the student distributed asset returns with 8 degrees of freedom. illustrates the relationship between the MSE and the estimation length, while plots the MSE as a function of the number of assets in the portfolio.

The structure of the comparison study is the same as in the case of the normally distributes data. In general, the behavior observed in and does not differ significantly from that obtained from the normal distribution. The best estimator is, as usual, our proposed estimator since it clearly dominates the other competitors for all estimation lengths and portfolio dimensions.

Figure 3. MSE of the expected Sharpe ratio estimators as a function of the estimation length

Note: This figure plots the MSE of our estimator of the expected Sharpe ratio derived in Equationequation (12), the Kourtis estimator and the Paulsen and Söhl estimator as a function of the estimation length T. The number of assets N is equal to 10. For each sample of returns of length T, simulated from a multivariate student distribution with 8 degrees of freedom, we compute the estimators of the out of sample Sharpe ratio. Then, we iterate the design 5000 times to compute the MSE.
Figure 3. MSE of the expected Sharpe ratio estimators as a function of the estimation length

Figure 4. MSE of the expected Sharpe ratio estimators as a function of the portfolio dimension

Note: This figure plots the MSE of our estimator of the expected Sharpe ratio derived in Equationequation (12), the Kourtis estimator and the Paulsen and Söhl estimator as a function of the number of assets N. The estimation length T is equal to 240. For each number of assets N, we simulate a sample of returns of length T from a multivariate student distribution with 8 degrees of freedom. Then, we compute the estimators of the out of sample Sharpe ratio. We iterate the design 5000 times to compute the MSE.
Figure 4. MSE of the expected Sharpe ratio estimators as a function of the portfolio dimension

To sum up, our estimator of the expected Sharpe ratio of estimated efficient portfolios shows superior performance compared with existing competitors. It has the lowest MSE for all sample sizes and portfolio dimensions regardless of the probability distribution of asset returns.

This outperformance is due, first, to the fact that our estimator captures all the errors involved in the estimated efficient portfolios. While Kourtis (Citation2016) and Paulsen and Söhl (Citation2020) neglect to incorporate the impact of the errors from estimating the covariance matrix when constructing their estimators by assuming a known covariance matrix, we take into account this feature. In fact, estimation errors in the covariance matrix affect the expected Sharpe ratio, especially, when the estimation length is small by comparison to the number of assets as demonstrated by Kan and Zhou (Citation2007). This explain, particularly, the outperformance of our estimator when computed with small estimation lengths.

Second, we accept some bias when constructing the estimator, which leads to a great decrease of the overall error. This conception allows beating the non-biased estimator of Paulsen and Söhl and the biased estimator of Kourtis.

6. Empirical study

In this section, we illustrate empirically the performance of our estimator of the expected Sharpe ratio and its competitors. We, first, describe the data used in this analysis. Then, we explain the methodology to evaluate the performance of these estimators. Finally, we present the results of the experiment.

6.1. Data

We use five empirical data sets of monthly returns outlined in . The data sets considered are from Ken French’s website. These are i) monthly excess returns of the standard 10 industry portfolios: Consumer-Discretionary, Consumer-Staples, Manufacturing, Energy, High-Tech, Telecommunication, Wholesale and Retail, Health, Utilities, and Others; ii) monthly excess returns of 10 portfolios sorted on momentum; iii) monthly excess returns of 25 portfolios formed on Size- and book-to-market; iv) monthly excess returns of 25 portfolios sorted by size and momentum; and v) monthly excess returns of 100 portfolios sorted by size and book-to-market. All the data sets cover the period from January 1927 to December 2017 except for the last data set which is available from January 1972 to December 2017.

Table 2. List of data sets

6.2. Methodology of performance evaluation

In each data set, we study how the estimators of the out-of-sample Sharpe ratio perform using a rolling window approach. Specifically, given a H-month-long data set of asset returns, we choose an estimation window of length T. Using return data corresponding to the chosen window, we compute our estimator (Sˉ), the Kourtis estimator (ζˉ) and the Paulsen and Söhl estimator (τˉ). We repeat this after rolling the window forward. This means estimation is repeated after adding data for the next month and dropping data for the earliest month. This is continued until all the available data is used. As a result, HT estimations of the out-of-sample Sharpe ratio of each estimator are produced.

We, also, compute the true expected Sharpe ratio as follows: First, we calculate the true parameters (i.e., μ and Σ) using the entire data set. Then, for each estimation window of length T, the Sharpe ratio of estimated efficient portfolios is computed using Equationequation (6). This process is continued by adding data for the next month and dropping the earliest data until the end of the data set is reached. Finally, we average on the resulting HT Sharpe ratio outcome. Given the HT series of the out-of-sample Sharpe ratio and the true expected Sharpe ratio, we compute the MSE of the estimators.

6.3. Results

reports the MSE of the estimators of the out-of-sample Sharpe ratio for empirical data using an estimation window of 240 months. clearly shows that our estimator performs the best among all data sets since it delivers the lowest MSE compared to its competitors. Even with a short estimation window (i.e., T=120), confirms the superiority of the suggested estimator of the Sharpe ratio. For example, for the SBM100 data set, the MSE of the competitors is about 10 times compared to our estimator when T=240. However, when T=120, the MSEs of the same competitors grows up to more than 400 times.

Table 3. MSE of the out-of-sample Sharpe ratio estimators for empirical data (T=240)

Table 4. MSE of the out-of-sample Sharpe ratio estimators for empirical data (T=120)

7. Conclusion

Efficient mean-variance portfolios are subject to estimation errors that affect their future performance. To evaluate the out-of-sample performance, this article derives a feasible estimator of the expected Sharpe ratio that captures all the errors involved in these portfolios.

In a simulation study, we find that our estimator dominates the existing competitors in the literature since it delivers the lowest MSE regardless off the size of the estimation length, the number of assets and the probability distribution of asset returns. Our estimation method works well, particularly, in practical investment settings (i.e., short estimation lengths). The empirical study confirms these results.

Our analysis suggests a number of potentially fruitful avenues for future research. It would be of interest to further improve the precision of the proposed estimator. Two techniques could be adopted: the address of a limitation of this work (i.e., the expected Sharpe ratio formula developed under first order Taylor approximation) by incorporating higher-order approximations and the development of accurate estimators of the unknown maximum Sharpe ratio.

Furthermore, future work could use the methods in this work to develop estimators of the Sharpe ratio for sample-based mean-variance rules that have been proposed in the literature to deal with the problem of estimation errors.

8. Appendix: Proofs

We state three lemmas that will be used along the proofs:

Lemma 1 For a bivariate function fx,y, a first-order Taylor series approximation to f around the point μx=Ex,μy=Ey is

fx,yfμx,μy+f xμx,μyxμx+f yμx,μyyμy.

The expected value of fx,y is

Efx,y=fμx,μy.

When fx,y=xy, then the expectation is

(17) Exy=Efx,y=fμx,μy=μxμy.(17)

Lemma 2 Under the multivariate normality assumption on rt, μˆ and Σˆ are independent and they have the following exact distributions:

(18) μˆ NNμ,Σ/T,(18)
(19) ΣˆWNT1,Σ/T,(19)

where WNT1,Σ/T is a Wishart distribution with T1 degrees of freedom and covariance matrix Σ/T.

The proof of the exact distributions of μˆ and Σˆ is a well-known result in econometrics. See, for instance, Muirhead (Citation1982), theorem 3.1.2.

Lemma 3 Let W=Σ12ΣˆΣ12, then W\~WNT1,IN/T, where IN is the identity matrix. The inverse moments of W are as follows (see, e.g., Haff (Citation1979)):

(20) EW1=TTN2IN,(20)
(21) EW2=T2T2TN1TN2TN4IN,(21)

where T>N+4.

9. Proof of proposition 1

If μ and Σ are unknown, then the estimated portfolio is wˆ=1γΣˆ1μˆ. The expected Sharpe ratio of this portfolio is

ESˆ=EμwˆwˆΣwˆ
=EμΣˆ1μˆμˆΣˆ1ΣΣˆ1μˆ
=EμΣˆ1μˆEμˆΣˆ1ΣΣˆ1μˆ
=EμΣ12W1Σ12μˆEμˆΣ12W2Σ12μˆ
=EEμΣ12W1Σ12μˆμˆEEμˆΣ12W2Σ12μˆμˆ
=EμΣ12EW1Σ12μˆEμˆΣ12EW2Σ12μˆ
=TTN2μΣ1μT2T2TN1TN2TN4(N+TμΣ1μT)
(22) =TN1TN4TN2T2NTθ2+1θ(22)

10. Proof of (10)

By expression (49) of Kan and Zhou (Citation2007), we have θˆ2 follows a non-central F distribution with non-centrality parameter λ=Tθ2:

θˆ2NTNFN,TNTθ2.

Theorem 3.1 of Kubokawa et al. (Citation1993) states that if a random variable wFp,nλ, then the unbiased estimator of λ is n2wp. Under quadratic loss, this estimator is dominated by

λ˜=maxn2wp,2n2p+2w.

Our adjusted estimator θ˜2 is then obtained by letting λ˜=Tθ˜2, λ=Tθ2, w=θˆ2, p=N and n=TN

Additional information

Funding

The authors received no direct funding for this research.

Notes on contributors

Bacem Benjlijel

Bacem Benjlijel is a PhD student in finance at the Faculty of Economics and Management of Nabeul, University of Carthage, Tunisia. Hatem Mansali is associate Professor of Finance at the Business School of Tunis, University of Manouba –Tunis (Tunisia) and Research Fellow at the Institut de Recherche en Gestion (University of Paris Est-France) and LIFE (Tunis – El Manar University). He holds a PhD Degree in Finance from the University of Paris Est (2006). He has recently published several academic papers in international refereed journals including Journal of Banking and Finance, International Journal of Managerial and Financial Accounting, Finance Contrôle Stratégie, Managerial Finance.

Notes

1. Fabozzi et al. (Citation2007), in a survey of managers at 38 asset management firms managing a total of $4.3 trillion in equities, find that the mean-variance optimization is by far the most used method in practice.

2. Amenc et al. (Citation2003) find that the majority of the distributors of hedge funds measure the performance of their investments using the Sharpe ratio.

3. If w=1, then the investor chooses the tangency portfolio composed of risky assets only.

References

  • Amenc, N., Martellini, L., & Vaissié, M. (2003). Benefits and risks of alternative investment strategies. Journal of Asset Management, 4(2), 96–16. https://doi.org/10.1057/palgrave.jam.2240097
  • Auer, B. R. (2015). Does the choice of performance measure influence the evaluation of commodity investments? International Review of Financial Analysis, 38, 142–150. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.irfa.2014.10.003
  • Chen, J., & Yuan, M. (2016). Efficient Portfolio Selection in a Large Market. Journal of Financial Econometrics, 14(3), 496–524. https://doi.org/10.1093/jjfinec/nbw003
  • DeMiguel, V., Garlappi, L., & Uppal, R. (2009). Optimal Versus Naive Diversification: How Inefficient is the 1/ N Portfolio Strategy? Review of Financial Studies, 22(5), 1915–1953. https://doi.org/10.1093/rfs/hhm075
  • Eling, M. (2008). Does the Measure Matter in the Mutual Fund Industry? Financial Analysts Journal, 64(3), 54–66. https://doi.org/10.2469/faj.v64.n3.6
  • Eling, M., & Schuhmacher, F. (2007). Does the choice of performance measure influence the evaluation of hedge funds? Journal of Banking & Finance, 31(9), 2632–2647. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jbankfin.2006.09.015
  • Fabozzi, F. J., Focardi, S., & Jonas, C. (2007). Trends in quantitative equity management: Survey results. Quantitative Finance, 7(2), 115–122. https://doi.org/10.1080/14697680701195941
  • Haff, L. (1979). An identity for the Wishart distribution with applications. Journal of Multivariate Analysis, 9(4), 531–544. https://doi.org/10.1016/0047-259X(79)90056-3
  • Kan, R., Wang, X., & Zhou, G. (2016). Optimal portfolio selection with and without risk-free asset. Working paper available at SSRN , 2729429.
  • Kan, R., & Zhou, G. (2007). Optimal Portfolio Choice with Parameter Uncertainty. The Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, 42(3), 621–656. https://doi.org/10.1017/S0022109000004129
  • Kourtis, A. (2016). The Sharpe ratio of estimated efficient portfolios. Finance Research Letters, 17, 72–78. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.frl.2016.01.009
  • Kubokawa, T., Robert, C., & Saleh, A. (1993). Estimation of noncentrality parameters. Canadian Journal of Statistics, 21(1), 45–57. https://doi.org/10.2307/3315657
  • Ledoit, O., & Wolf, M. (2012). Nonlinear shrinkage estimation of large-dimensional covariance matrices. The Annals of Statistics, 40(2), 1024–1060. https://doi.org/10.1214/12-AOS989
  • Markowitz, H. (1952). Portfolio selection. The Journal of Finance, 7(1), 77–91. https://doi.org/10.2307/2975974
  • Markowitz, H. (1959). Portfolio Selection: Efficient Diversification of Investments. Yale University Press.
  • Muirhead, R. J. (editor). (1982). Aspects of Multivariate Statistical Theory. Wiley Series in Probability and Statistics. John Wiley & Sons, Inc..
  • Paulsen, D., & Söhl, J. (2020). Noise fit, estimation error and a Sharpe information criterion. Quantitative Finance, 20(6), 1027–1043. https://doi.org/10.1080/14697688.2020.1718746
  • Sharpe, W. F. (1966). Mutual Fund Performance. The Journal of Business, 39(1), 119–138. https://doi.org/10.1086/294846
  • Sharpe, W. F. (1994). The Sharpe Ratio. The Journal of Portfolio Management, 21(1), 49–58. https://doi.org/10.3905/jpm.1994.409501
  • Shi, F., Shu, L., Yang, A., & He, F. (2020). Improving Minimum-Variance Portfolios by Alleviating Overdispersion of Eigenvalues. Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, 55(8), 2700–2731. https://doi.org/10.1017/S0022109019000899
  • Tu, J., & Zhou, G. (2004). Data-generating process uncertainty: What difference does it make in portfolio decisions? Journal of Financial Economics, 72(2), 385–421. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jfineco.2003.05.003
  • Tu, J., & Zhou, G. (2011). Markowitz meets Talmud: A combination of sophisticated and naive diversification strategies. Journal of Financial Economics, 99(1), 204–215. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jfineco.2010.08.013