4,412
Views
0
CrossRef citations to date
0
Altmetric
FINANCIAL ECONOMICS

A theoretical framework for simulating systemic risk and its application to analysis of the banking system

ORCID Icon | (Reviewing editor)
Article: 1986930 | Received 26 Jun 2020, Accepted 25 Sep 2021, Published online: 05 Nov 2021

Abstract

Risk of basic defaults and contagious defaults are two main sources of bank systemic risk. In this paper, a theoretical framework is proposed to classify the time evolution of the basic defaults and contagious defaults using sequences of daily financial data. The new theoretical framework combines an existing asset value estimation algorithm and obligation clearing algorithm to calculate the time evolution of systemic risk. The asset value estimation algorithm is used to estimate the asset values of the banks each day and the obligation clearing algorithm is used to calculate systemic risk given the tuples of data each day. This framework is applied to assess the systemic risk of the Nigerian banking system between 2008 and 2014 when the economy was hit by the financial meltdown. The main findings depict that the risk of the basic defaults was high during this period while contagious default seldom appeared. It is also found that the Nigerian banking system was more stable in 2010 and 2012 than in other years, while it was seriously unstable in 2008, 2011, and 2014. The findings would assist in monitoring systemic risk in the Nigerian banking system.

PUBLIC INTEREST STATEMENT

The global credit crisis that started in 2007 has highlighted the need of addressing incomplete reforms, one of them being the contribution of systemic risk in destabilizing the financial markets. The crisis has shown how systemic risk can propagate in the financial system causing failure of financial institutions and ultimately distress of the global economy. Based on that, this simulation-based study proposes a theoretical framework to assess systemic risk in the Nigerian banking system from 2008 to 2014 using a sequence of daily financial data. Results depict that the Nigerian banking system was more stable in the years 2010 and 2012 than in other years. The approach proposed in study will provide insights for regulators in the management of systemic risk.

1. Introduction

The collapse of Lehman Brothers showed that the defaults of large banks can set in motion a chain of insolvencies in the financial markets causing distress and even failure of some key institutions in the financial system leading to financial crisis (Sedunov, Citation2016). The crisis emphasizes the need to identify the underlying factors that destabilize the financial institutions which could result in systemic risk.

Systemic risk has been defined in different ways by different scholars and policymakers. Schwarz (Citation2008) has reconciled the different definitions of systemic risk and ultimately gives the general definition of it. The risk that an economic shock such as market or institutional failure (i) triggers (through a panic or otherwise) either (x) the failure of a chain of markets or institutions or (y) a chain of significant losses to financial institutions, (ii) results in substantial financial-market price volatility. It is characterized as a way in which the distress of one institution endangers the rest of the financial system. The reason for this is that financial intermediaries are said to be either too big to fail, too interconnected to fail or too important to fail (Bramer et al., Citation2014). The above four scenarios indicate the many dimensions of systemic risk in the banking market. To be more clear and incorporate the four indicators mentioned above, systemic risk is interpreted as the threat which threaten the stability of the banking sector, generated by both single institutions (too big, too interconnected, too important) as well as group of banks (too many).

Therefore, we can construct two main components to illustrate and model systemic risk based on the definition. One component is basic default that an initial random shock affects even to the point of failing one financial institution and the other is contagious default that a contagion transmits such negative effects to other institutions on the system. Various scholars have addressed the basic defaults, namely, systemic risk of single institutions for instance, Acharya et al. (Citation2010), Adrian and Brunnermeier (Citation2016); Tarashev et al (Citation2010), while others deal with systemic risk of the contagious defaults such as Huang et al. (Citation2011), Illing and Liu (Citation2006).

Nigeria economy has passed different stages of economic crisis, apart from the global financial crisis in 2008; it has also been affected by the effects of crude oil crash in 2014 (Osadume & Mbachu, Citation2017). All of these could have a significant impact on the Nigerian banking system. Therefore, this paper uses the data of 10 major banks in Nigeria in terms of assets value and test the extent of systemic risk in the banking system. Thus, supported by the empirical evidence in Nigerian banking system, this study evaluates systemic risk in the Nigerian banking system based on the proposed theoretical framework.

The rest of the paper is organized as follows. Section 2 provides literatures on the measures of systemic risk. Section 3 provides the theoretical framework underlying the evolution of basic defaults and contagion defaults. Section 4 provides the data used. Section 5 presents the results and lastly section 6 provides the concluding remarks.

2. Literature review

Two approaches pertaining to the identification and measurement of systemic risk have been proposed. The first approach is the traditional approach that analyzes systemic risk based on stock market. This includes measures such as Value at risk (VaR) and Expected Shortfall which measure systemic risk for liquid positions operating under normal market conditions over a short period of time. Adrian and Brunnermeier (Citation2016) proposed the concept of conditional value at risk to measure the contribution to systemic risk (Δ CoVaR) from each bank. Acharya et al. (Citation2010) proposed systemic expected shortfall in order to gauge listed financial institutions contributions to systemic risk. Huang et al. (Citation2009; Citation2010,, Citation2011) proposed to measure the risk of a financial system by the insurance premium that would be required to cover losses in a distressed condition.

In terms of assessing systemic risk, the traditional approach measures systemic losses conditional on each financial institution being in distress. These measures take into account the size, the probability of default, and the correlation of each financial institution. However, the correlation fails to capture the interconnectedness sufficiently because it does not consider the various interactions such as contagious defaults or the relationship between interconnectedness and systemic importance in a financial system. Besides measures like VaR and MES has been confronted for not capturing the systemic risk of the financial system as a whole as it looks on systemic risk of the banking system in isolation.

Based on that, this paper focuses on the second approach to analyze systemic risk that is network model. The network models examine the interbank network as a contagion channel that is when some banks are not able to honor their promises in the interbank market, they might push other banks into insolvency which might again lead to defaults of other banks. In normal times, the interbank market ensures efficient liquidity redistribution from banks with surplus liquidity to banks with a shortage of liquidity and thus serves as an absorber of idiosyncratic liquidity shocks. In turbulent situation, however, interbank markets can become a channel for liquidity contagion due to liquidity hoarding by banks and/or credit risk contagion due to credit losses on interbank exposures.

The literature on contagion starts with the work of Allen and Gale (Citation2000) who give a model of risk propagation through interbank exposure network. They show that if there is no liquidity shock, all banks can survive; however in liquidity shock case, number of defaulting banks change depending on network completeness. Freixas et al. (Citation2000) consider that for contagion to happen in a system with money-centre banks where the institutions on the periphery are connected to banks at the centre but not to each other depends on the precise values of the models parameters. Upper (Citation2011) describes that the possibility for contagion depends on the precise structure of the interbank market, for the same shocks some structures would result in contagion while others would not, a complete structure of claims, in which every bank has symmetric exposures to all other banks is much more stable than an incomplete structure, where banks are linked only to one neighbor. Disconnected structures are more vulnerable to contagion than complete structures, but they prevent contagion from spreading to all banks. Finally, show that the possibility for contagion in a system with money-centre banks, where the institutions on the periphery are linked to banks at the centre but not to each other, crucially depends on the precise values of the model’s parameters.

A number of the studies in this approach are based on Eisenberg and Noe (Citation2001) who define a clearing payment process for interbank networks considering all possible contagion effects in a static network structure. Elsinger et al. (Citation2006) include bankruptcy costs in their simulation of the Austrian banking system and show that the system is able to absorb shocks well for small bankruptcy costs while large dead weight losses can wipe out the banking system. Rogers and Veraart (Citation2013) model clearing in the interbank networks with bankruptcy costs and provide an analysis of the situations in which banks have incentives to bail out distressed bank. Memmel et al. (Citation2011) use the bilateral interbank liabilities of 15 German banks and run simulations on idiosyncratic defaults for each of the institution allowing only one bank to fail at time, failure is explained at Tier 1 capital falling below 6% of risk weighted assets. Bramer et al. (Citation2014) introduce a network model to assess system risk in the banking sector and run simulations based on theoretical data. Their paper build on the network simulation of Memmel et al. (Citation2011) and incorporate an exogenous shock on the market that comprehends the primary default of one or more institutions and examine the degree of volatility of the system. Ebrahimi Kahou and Lehar (Citation2017) give a detailed overview of systemic risk measures.

Despite the fact that the researches on contagion risk in the interbank banking system have made great progress, there are some constraints in existing research. Most of the studies are based on static network structures (fixed bank lending matrixes) and static bank systems (fixed bank balance sheets). However, an interbank network system portrays high complex dynamics. Thus, this study examines systemic risk based on the dynamic financial networks. For instance, Eisenberg-Noe framework describes simultaneous defaults for one period and not on the dynamic multiperiod which is applies to this study. Therefore, this study extends a framework to multiperiod setting which borrows from the framework of Kanno (Citation2015) and theoretically analyze the Nigerian interbank market. Kanno (Citation2015) considered the multiperiod scenario but didn’t take into account the dynamic changing of the interbank market. Through the dynamic changing of the interbank market, both the total asset value and equity value of the bank change dynamically and this can be estimated from real world data instead of theoretical assumption.

Few studies have examined the dynamic model of network structure such as, Georg (Citation2013), Lux (Citation2015), Xu et al. (Citation2016), and Bluhm et al. (Citation2014). But these literatures did not consider the effect of systemic random shocks in the banking system, they almost considered credit and liquidity shocks. Thus, for shock scenarios, this study adds a systemic shock artificially in the system to observe the time evolution of the banking system and hence measure the systemic risk. Stated in other words, the systemic risk is measured by checking whether a bank system can withstand certain strength of systemic shock. Some banks may be bankrupt at a certain time point due to this artificially added systemic shock, therefore both the structure and the state of the bank change dynamically. The systemic risk is measured by recording the number of banks which undergo bankrupt during the time. If the strength of the systemic shock is fixed, then a bank system with more banks which undergo bankrupt during the whole-time course of its evolution is believed to suffer more systemic risk.

The study defines the methodology and conduct analysis of the theoretical framework, and present the results of the systemic risk of Nigeria banking system. Specifically, an optimization procedure is conducted to estimate the bilateral exposures matrix using the aggregate balance sheet data on loans and deposits from African market web site. The study uses the estimated bilateral exposures matrix to theoretically analyze the network structure of the interbank market in Nigeria. From the daily market capitalization data, the market values of assets at each day and the drifts and volatilities of their returns for each bank are estimated using the stochastic model and the maximum likelihood estimation method (Duan et al., Citation2005). This study also endeavors to examine bank defaults which are classified as basic defaults and contagious defaults which generally trigger domino effect. With regard to the contagious default the study uses the Eisenberg and Noe framework that is based on a mathematical proof showing that there always exists a unique vector for simultaneously clearing the obligations of all participants in the system. The vector is developed under mild regularity using a fixed point theorem. By using the in and out degree and network centrality measures the research explain how banks play an important role in the interbank market.

3. Theoretical frameworks

This research considers the interconnectedness of the Nigerian bank network, which allows the analysis of transmission of systemic risk through bilateral exposures, possibly causing contagious defaults that are triggered by banks basic default. and illustrate the theoretical frameworks of this study. show an example bank network structure of ten banks connected with each other through bilateral exposures which are described by matrix X in ). ) shows the bank balance sheet of banki. In the balance sheet, vi represents the assets of banki, ai stands for the interbank assets of banki, Di is the liability of banki, and liis the interbank liability of bank i. If the bank balance sheet of bank i shows that the assets are smaller than the liability, namely vi+ ai <Di +li, then bank i defaults by the definition of basic default. Through bilateral exposures, the basic default of banki can cause the contagious defaults to the banks that connect to bank i. shows the flowchart of the process of the theoretical frameworks. In section 3.1, the methodology for estimating the matrix of bilateral exposures is described and then the methods of estimating the time evolution of the bank balance sheet of banking system in is presented Section 3.2. Finally, the methods for estimating the time evolution of basic defaults and contagion defaults are proposed in sections 3.3 and 3.4, respectively.

Figure 1. The theoretical framework

Figure 1. The theoretical framework

Figure 2. The estimation process of the theoretical framework

Figure 2. The estimation process of the theoretical framework

3.1. Estimation of bilateral exposure matrix

In this section the study describes the methodology for estimating the bilateral exposure matrix that is described in ). Usually the interbank market of participants comprises central banks, commercial banks, investment banks, cooperative banks, security companies, private banking, and asset management companies, real estate and mortgage banks, and specialized government institutions. To fully fill the scope of this study, it is required to determine the interbank exposures. Unfortunately, this ideal data quality is rare. The interbank exposures cannot be fully observed but has to be partially estimated from balance sheet data. Initial total interbank assets data aiand liabilities data li in the balance sheet described in ) usually correspond with two relevant accounting items, loans and advances to banks (ai) and deposits from banks (li). The lending relationships in the interbank market will be represented by N×Nnominal interbank matrix X as shown in ), where xij represents the lending loans of bank i to bank j, jxij = ai represents the total interbank assets of bank i, and  ixij = lj means the total interbank liability of bankj. It has to hold that

(1) iai=jlj=xΣ(1)

where xΣ is size of the interbank market. It is assumed that the diagonal elements of X have to be zero. Therefore, the prior matrix of x0 is set as follows:

(2) xij0=oforanyi=jailj,fori<>j.(2)

However,x0 values violate the summing constraints expressed in EquationEquation (1). The standard way in the literature to handle this problem is to determine an admissible matrix X that minimizes the Kullback-Leibler divergence with respect to some specified nonnegative prior matrixx0 . The Kullback-Leibler divergence for nonnegative but otherwise arbitrary X is given by

(3) mini=1nj=1nxijxΣlog(xijxΣxij0 x0Σ(3)

Where x0Σ is the sum of all entries in x0 It is easy to verify that EquationEquation (3) is also equivalent to EquationEquation (4) as follows:

(4) mini=1nj=1nxijlog(xijx0ij(4)

Therefore, the estimation of X conditional on the prior matrix x0 is given by the solution of

mini=1nj=1nxijlog(xijx0ij)

Subject to i=inxij=ai, j=1nxij=lj,

(5) xij0(5)

where 0log0 = 0;0log0/0 = 0. An algorithm of realizing the theoretical estimation

of Xis summarized as follows.

3.1.1. The algorithm for estimating the bilateral exposures matrix

Step 1: Start the iteration by setting xij0=ailj if i1j otherwisexij0=0.

Step 2: Take the rows constraint and set:

(6) xij1=xij0aii=1Nj=1Nailjforalli1,N.(6)

Step 3: Take the columns constraint and set:

(7) xij2=xij1lii=1Nj=1Nailjforallj1,N.(7)

The K iteration runs across the rows and columns constraints show that:

(8) xijk=xijk1aii=1Nj=1Nailjforalli1,N(8)
(9) xijk+1=xijklii=1Nj=1Nailjforallj1,N(9)

The iteration is stopped as soon as some distance measure, e.g., the Euclidean distance, between xijk+1 and xijk1 is smaller than a prespecified ε>0.

3.2. Estimation of the time evolution ofvi

Asset value is not daily observable. However, asset value can be collected in the bank balance sheet at the end of each year, while the equity market price of banks can be observed by stock price on each day. The time t is measured in units of day. This paper also gives a method to estimate asset values of each day (time evolution of asset value) according to the equity market data of banks. Assume that the asset value vi of bank i follow a geometric Brownian motion with drift μi and volatilityσi:

(10) dVi=μiVidt+σiVidz(10)

Then equity Ei(t) can be seen as a call option on the assets of bank i with a strike price equal to the future notional value of bank i′s debt Di(t), which is assumed to have a maturity of t. Then the value of bank equity is given by the Black-Scholes model as follows:

(11) Eit=vitNdtDitNdtσiT(11)

where T = 365 days, t represents the evolution of days and

(12) dt=lnVit/Dit+σi2/2TσiT(12)

In the stock market one can observe a time series of equity prices Ei(t) and read the face value of bank debt Di(0) from the balance sheet. All bank debt is assumed to be insured and will therefore grow at the risk-free rate r. Then Dit=Di0ert . Given the initial data of vi(0), and time series data of Ei0,Ei1,EiT,Di0,Di0,Di1,.DiT, and the arbitrary initial value of μi0,σi0, it is easy to get the estimation of Viˆ1,Viˆ2;.. ViˆT according to the EquationEquation (11). Then the following maximization likelihood function is used to estimate the parameters μi and σi, which is proposed by Duan et al. (Citation2005)

(13) L(Ui,σi;Vˆi(1),Vˆi(2),,Vˆi(T))=T2ln(2πσi2h)T2k=1T(Ri(k)(uiσi22)h)2σi2hk=1TlnVˆt(13)

whereRi(k)=ln(Vˆi(t)/Vˆi(t1)),h=1/365

After getting the estimation value of μi and σi the evolution of vit can be estimated as follows:

(14) Vit=vi0euiσi22th+σithZit(14)

where zi(t) obeys normal distribution (N (0, 1)).

To test the stability of the bank network system, a systemic shock is added to the banking system. If the banks withstand a strong shock, then it can be said that the system is stable. If the banking system collapses when a weak shock applies, then it can be concluded that the bank system is unstable. Thus, this research applies a medium shock to count the numbers of banks which undergoes bankruptcy. If the probabilities of the banks which undergo bankruptcy are large for a medium shock, then the bank system is unstable. The shock is added to the system by replacing zi(t) in EquationEquation (14) with 1ξ zit+ξωtwhere ξ represents the strength of the systemic shock and ωt is the systemic shock which is the same for all banks, ω (t) follows the normal distribution (N(0;1)) where ξ= 0.1.Thus the evolution of Vit (t) can be estimated as follows:

(15) Vit=vi0euiσi22th+σith1ξ zit+ξωt(15)

3.3. The basic default of banks

The basic default of bank i occur due to its insolvent situation, i.e.

(16) vit+aitDitlit<0(16)

where vi(t) is calculated by EquationEquation (14), and Di(t) can be described as follows:

(17) Dit=Di0ert(17)

wherer is the risk-free rate for each day, ait and lit will be described in Section 3.4.

3.4. The contagion default of banks

The contagion default of banks occurs due to the interbank market. Here, the paper presents a framework to calculate the contagion default of banks based on the clearing payment mechanism proposed by Eisenberg and Noe (Citation2001). The paper extends the clearing payment mechanism of Eisenberg and Noe (Citation2001) to suit the calculation of the time evolution of the contagion default (time evolution of systemic risk). In the present paper, the clearing payment mechanism simultaneously solves the interbank payment amounts of all the banks on daily basis. The banking system is represented as Xt;et, where Xt is a N×Nbilateral exposures matrix, and et =vitDit as shown in . This study defines a new matrix Πt that is derived fromXt by normalizing the entries by total interbank liabilities:

ijt=xjit/litiflit>0,0otherwise (18)

where lit=jxjit. The present paper describes the banking system as a tuple Πt;et;xt for which a clearing payment vector pt is defined. The clearing payment vector has to respect limited liability of banks and proportional sharing in case of default. Thus, the clearing payment vector denotes the total payments made by the banks under the clearing mechanism. It is defined by

(19) pit==litifj=1Njitpjt+eilit,j=1Njitpjt+eitlit>j=1Njitpjt+eit00ifj=1Njitpjt+eit<0.(19)

The study adopts the default algorithm developed by Eisenberg and Noe (Citation2001) to find a clearing payment vector. They proved that under mild regularity conditions, a unique clearing payment vector always exists for Πt;et;xt.These results apply to the multiperiod setting.

3.4.1. Contagious default

Although Bank i does not default according to EquationEquation (16), it may default when other banks are not able to keep their promises. In other words, contagious default of bank i occurs if

(20) j=1Njitpjt+eitlit<0(20)

The number of contagious defaults of banks can be calculated by EquationEquation (20). At each time step t, the detailed algorithm of calculating the contagious defaults of banks can be referred to Eisenberg and Noe (Citation2001).

3.4.2. The evolution of the bilateral exposuresXt+1,ait+1, andljt+1

After calculating a clearing payment vector according to the algorithm in Eisenberg and Noe (Citation2001) at time step t, the new matrix of X at the time step t+1is calculated. The following is the algorithm of calculating the evolution of the matrix X.

Step 1i=1. At time stept, calculate the net claim value of bank i asΔvit =j=1Njitpjt+eitlit. If ΔVit>0 (the clearing payment vector of bank i will be pit=lit in this case), let χi=1 and go to Step 3. Otherwise, go to Step 2.

Step 2: Contagion default of bank i occurs whenΔvit <0, so bank i can pay only a part of the liabilities to other banks. The ratio is defined as follows:

(21) χi=j=1Njitpjt+eitli(21)

Step 3: Update the assets values and liability values of bank j from time step t +1 to T as follows:

Vjt+1:T=Vjtχixij
(22) Djt+1:T=Djtχixij(22)

Step 4: IfΔvit<0, then we clear out bank i from the network bank system,

xj,it=0
(23) xi,jt=0(23)

Step 5: Leti=i+1. Go to step 2.

Step 6: Recalculate the bilateral exposures matrix xt+1according to the algorithm in Section 3.1.1. Therefore, the evolution ofait+1, and ljt+1 is described as:

(24) ait+1=j=1Nxi,jt+1(24)
ljt+1=i=1Nxi,jt+1.

3.4.3. The measure of the stability of the bank network system

The probability of the basic default of banki, Pbi is calculated as:

(25) Pbi=NbiNs(25)

where Nbi is the number of runs of the simulation during which basic default of bank i occurs and Ns is the total number of runs of the simulation. Similarly, the calculation of the probability of the contagious default of banki,Pci, is calculated as:

(26) Pci=NciNs(26)

where Nci is the number of runs of the simulation during which contagious default of bankioccurs. The stability of the bank system Stis defined as:

(27) St=1iPbi+iPciN(27)

Where N is the number of banks in the banking system.

4. Data

In this study the financial data of Nigerian banks are collected from African markets database. The study involves 10 major commercial banks out of 15 publicly traded commercial banks in Nigeria from 2008–2014, namely Access bank, Diamond bank, FBN Holdings, Fidelity bank, Guaranty bank, Skye bank, Sterling bank, Union bank of Africa, United bank of Africa, and Zenith international bank. The sample of 10 banks is selected based on banks with large assets value (NSE). The study concentrates on bank accounts and not on group accounts and thus collect data on bank total assets, total liabilities, interbank lending and interbank borrowing. As the need is to estimate the market value of the assets from equity data, only publicly traded banks are considered. The interest rates of country during the period of 2008–2014 are collected from the Central bank of Nigeria and run simulations based on the collected data.

5. Results

5.1. Network structure and estimation of bilateral exposures matrix

The bilateral exposures matrix X is estimated as stated in EquationEquation (1) and use the matrix to examine the network structure of the Nigerian banking system. For this case, the Nigerian interbank network is analyzed using the network centrality measures. This paper uses degree measures to obtain information on the roles played by the market participants. Usually the degree of a node is considered as a proxy variable for interconnectedness and explains the number of edges connected to a node.

The in-degree shows the amount of money going toward (borrowed by) a bank (corresponding to ai in EquationEquation (1). For simplicity, this study uses the ratio of the money borrowed by the bank to the total money borrowed by all banks to measure in-degree of bank i, i.e. the in-degree of bank i is ai/iai. Similarly, the out-degree of bank i is li/ili. The total degree of a bank is the summation of its in-degree and out-degree. These measures, hence give a sense of investment and funding diversifications. describes the ratio of borrowing and lending for each bank as expressed by the in-degree and out-degree relationship. Results depict that there are banks that borrow more than lending while others lend more than borrowing. Banks like Access bank, FBH, Union bank of Nigeria, and Skye bank borrow more than they lend to other banks by average of 43.1 %, 22%, 18.4% and 7.7% respectively from 2008 to 2014. Banks like Zenith International Bank, United Bank of Africa, Fidelity Bank, Guaranty bank, Diamond bank, and Sterling bank lend more than they borrow by the average of 28.4%, 17.2%, 8.6%, 8.4%, 8.3%, and 4.3%, respectively, from 2008 to 2004. Thus, banks which borrow (lend) more than they lend (borrow) in the Nigerian banking system in terms of percentage are examined as follows. The list of banks that borrow in order of preference in the average of seven years includes Access 43.1%, FBH 22%, Union bank of Nigeria 18.4 %, Skye bank 7.7 %, United Bank of Africa 6.1%, Diamond Bank 5.71%, Sterling bank 2.1%, Guaranty bank 1.9%, Fidelity bank 1.7%, and Zenith International bank 0% while banks that funds in order of preference includes Zenith International Bank 28.4%, FBN 20%, United bank of Africa 17.2%, Fidelity 8.6%, Guaranty bank 8.4%, Diamond bank 8.3%, Skye bank 7.3%, Access bank 6.6%, Union Bank of Nigeria 5.3%, and Sterling bank 4.3 %.

Figure 3. In-degree and out-degree for each bank (the vertical shows the percentage of the amount of money borrowed or lent by a bank while horizontal axis represents time in years)

Figure 3. In-degree and out-degree for each bank (the vertical shows the percentage of the amount of money borrowed or lent by a bank while horizontal axis represents time in years)

5.2. Estimation of market variables

This study estimates the market values of assets and the drifts and volatilities of the assets returns for each bank using the maximum likelihood method as explained earlier.

Drift rate indicates the development of the bank. If the drift rate is greater than 0, the trend of the development of the bank is upward and vice versa. The volatility of the assets value of the bank affects the stability of the bank, if the volatility is small then the development of the bank is more stable compared to when volatility is high. shows the variations of the drift rate. It depicts the variations of the drift rate for the ten banks involved in the study. The general findings show that the banks with the larger drift rate are Access bank, Diamond Bank, United Bank of Africa, Union Bank of Nigeria, Sterling Bank, and Zenith International bank. This implies that these banks are developing better than others. The banks with lower drift rates are FBN Holdings, Fidelity Bank, Guaranty bank, and Skye bank, indicating that the development trends of these banks are weaker than the earlier ones. portrays volatility of the bank assets and hence reveals the stability of the bank. The banks with the larger volatility comprise United Bank for Africa and Access Bank; this suggests that these banks may be more unstable compared to others. Banks with lower volatility include Diamond bank, FBN Holdings, Fidelity, Guaranty, Skye bank, Sterling bank, Union bank of Nigeria, and Zenith International bank; these banks are more stable.

Figure4. Variations of the drift rate (Vertical axis represents drift rate while horizontal axis represents time

Figure4. Variations of the drift rate (Vertical axis represents drift rate while horizontal axis represents time

Figure 5. Variations in the volatility of the assets value

Figure 5. Variations in the volatility of the assets value

Assets value implies the price an asset would fetch in the marketplace. Market value is also commonly used to refer to the market capitalization of a publicly traded company. Market value can fluctuate a great deal over periods of time, and is substantially influenced by the business cycle. Market values plunge during the bear markets that accompany recessions, and rise during the bull markets that are a feature of economic expansion. portrays the market values of the selected banks which shows some banks increasing their market value over time like Zenith International Bank, Sterling bank, Diamond bank, Access bank, and United bank of Africa, while FBN Holdings, Fidelity bank, Guaranty bank, and Skye bank suffer a tremendous decrease of their market value.

Figure 6. Variations in the asset values for selected banks

Figure 6. Variations in the asset values for selected banks

5.3. The stability of the Nigeria network system

In order to examine the stability of the Nigerian network system data were simulated as shown in . The findings show that there were seldom contagious defaults in Nigeria, basic defaults seemed to appear. The results also show that the Nigeria bank network system is more stable in years 2010 and 2012 than in other years, while in years 2008, 2011, and 2014, the Nigeria bank network system is seriously unstable.

Table 1. The stability of the Nigerian network system; the total number of runs of the simulation Ns =10,000

5.3.1. The evolution of the Nigerian network system

In this subsection, the evolution of the Nigerian network system is analyzed. From , it is shown that basic defaults of all the banks occurred in 2008, which means a very high systemic risk (It is worth noting that theoretical defaults of these banks do not mean that these banks really went bankrupt, because in reality, banks can go on operating even when its liability is larger than its assets). However, the need is to know the evolution of the Nigerian network system in 2008, so the evolution of the Nigeria network system for one run of the simulation is analyzed, which is shown in . It is found that the first bank to default is Sterling bank, although its connectivity is very small. The connectivity is the main reason for contagion. Therefore, small connectivity does not prevent the default of Sterling bank. Then, what caused Sterling bank to default firstly? It is found that from the drift rate of Sterling bank is the largest negative and from the volatility was increasing in 2008, which caused the evolution of assets of Sterling bank to gradually decrease as shown in . Therefore, the reason of basic defaults for the Nigerian network system mainly is caused by the drift rate, the volatility, and the evolution of assets.

Figure 7. The evolution of the Nigerian network system in 2008

Figure 7. The evolution of the Nigerian network system in 2008

In 2008, the drift values of most of banks in Nigeria are negative; the volatility of most banks is increasing, and the evolution of assets of most banks also gradually decreasing, which answers the reason of the occurrence of the basic defaults of all the banks in 2008. shows the default sequence of banks in the Nigerian network system while shows the evolution of default banks in other years. For individual bank, Union Bank of Nigeria is most unstable bank during the time. However, in 2008 and 2014, Union Bank of Nigeria is more stable than other years. In addition, it is found that its assets achieve the largest value among all the banks in 2008, but gradually decrease from 2008 to 2014 as shown in . Until 2013, its assets remained stable. Therefore, in 2014, Union Bank of Nigeria improves its stability largely. Between years 2009 and 2014, Zenith International bank was the most stable bank among all banks; its assets value is gradually increasing year by year between 2009 and 2014 (see ), which is due to its positive drift rate.

Table 2. The evolution of bank defaults in years 2009–2014

The size of each node represents the total percentage of in-degree and out-degree of each bank and the number of size is marked beside each node.

6. Conclusions

This paper proposed a new theoretical framework to reveal the time evolution of the systemic risk by calculating the number of defaults of banks using sequences of daily financial data. The framework combines the asset value estimation algorithm and obligation clearing algorithm to calculate time evolution of the systemic risk. The asset value estimation algorithm was used to estimate the asset values of the banks at each day which are used to compute time evolution of systemic risk. The obligation clearing algorithm was used to calculate the systemic risk given the tuples of data each day.

The theoretical framework proposed in this paper was used to analyze the Nigerian bank system. This paper examined the network structure of the Nigerian interbank market using centrality measures. Besides, it assessed the interconnectedness of each bank in the interbank market using the in-degree and out-degree measures, which helped to identify the most important banks in the Nigeria banking system. The paper also examined the contagious defaults in the Nigeria banking system and theoretically analyzed the mechanisms of contagious defaults conditional on the basic defaults. In contrast to the Western banks, the findings reveal the occurrence of basic defaults while contagious defaults are seldom observable; the reason for this is that the Africa’s stock market capitalization is still very low compared to world capitalization, furthermore African banking assets represent only a small portion of global banking assets.

It was also found that the Nigerian bank network system is more stable in years 2010 and 2012 than in other years, while in years 2008, 2011, and 2014, the Nigerian bank network system is seriously unstable. For individual bank, the Union Bank of Nigeria is most unstable, however, in 2014; the Union Bank of Nigeria improves its stability largely. Between years 2009 and 2014, the Zenith International bank is the most stable bank among all banks.

The method of estimating bilateral exposure matrix in this paper assumes that the topology of the interbank network is complete network and does not reproduce incomplete interbank market. Depending on the actual network structure this may negatively or positively bias the results. In future, one can adopt both the maximum entropy estimation method, Upper (Citation2011) and minimum density approach, Anand et al. (Citation2015) to estimate the bilateral exposure matrix, and then analyze the systemic risk in financial networks.

Acknowledgments

The author is very thankful for the comments of the Editor and the anonymous reviewers which significantly improved this work.

Disclosure statement

No potential conflict of interest was reported by the author(s).

Additional information

Funding

This research did not receive any specific grant from funding agencies.

Notes on contributors

Chirongo Moses Keregero

Chirongo Moses Keregero (PhD) is a Lecturer in Accounting and Finance at The University of Dodoma (UDOM). He has published numerous papers in international peer reviewed journals. His research interests fall within the following areas: Financial risk management, Financial markets and products, Investment analysis, Corporate finance and Financial stability.

References

  • Acharya, V. V., Pedersen, L. H., Philippon, T., & Richardson, M., (2010). Measuring systemic risk. Federal Bank of Cleveland Working paper 10–19.
  • Adrian, T., & Brunnermeier, M. K., (2016).CoVaR, American economic review.106, 1705–1741.
  • Allen, F., & Gale, D. (2000). Financial contagion. Journal of Political Economy, 108(1), 1–34. https://doi.org/10.1086/262109
  • Anand, K., Craig, B. R., & Von Peter, G. (2015). Filling in the Blanks: Network Structure and Interbank Contagion. Quantitative Finance, 15(4), 625–636. https://doi.org/10.1080/14697688.2014.968195
  • Bluhm, M., Faia, E., & Krahnen, J. P. (2014). Endogenous banks networks, cascades and systemic risk, SSRN.
  • Bramer, P., Gischer, H., & Lucke, C. (2014). A simulation approach to evaluate systemic risk. European Journal of Political Economy, 34, S53–S64. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ejpoleco.2013.04.006
  • Duan,J.C.,Gauthier,G., & Simonato,J.G. (2005). On the equivalence of the KMV and maximum likelihood methods for structural credit risk models.Groupe d'e'tudes et de recherche en analyse des de'cisions. www.defaultrisk.com/ppmodel97.htmDuan
  • Ebrahimi Kahou, M., & Lehar, A. (2017). Macroprudential policy, A review. Journal of Financial Stability, 29, 92–105. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jfs.2016.12.005
  • Eisenberg, L., & Noe, T. H. (2001). Systemic risk in financial systems. Management Science, 47(2), 236–249. https://doi.org/10.1287/mnsc.47.2.236.9835
  • Elsinger, H., Lehar, A., & Summer, M. (2006). Risk assessment for banking systems. Management Science, 52(9), 1301–1314. https://doi.org/10.1287/mnsc.1060.0531
  • Freixas, X., Parigi, B. M., & Rochet, J. (2000). Systemic risk, interbank relations, and liquidity provision by the central bank. Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking, 32(3), 611–640. https://doi.org/10.2307/2601198
  • Georg, C. (2013). The Effect of the Interbank Network Structure on Contagion and Common Shocks. Journal of Banking and Finance, 37(7), 2216–2228. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jbankfin.2013.02.032
  • Huang, X., Zhou, H., & Zhu, H. (2009). A framework for assessing the systemic risk of major financial institutions. Journal of Banking and Finance, 33(11), 2036–2049. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jbankfin.2009.05.017
  • Huang, X., Zhou, H., & Zhu, H. (2010). Assessing the systemic risk of a heterogeneous portfolio of banks during the recent financial crisis. Journal of Financial Stability, 8(3), 193–205. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jfs.2011.10.004
  • Huang, X., Zhou, H., & Zhu, H. (2011). Systemic risk contributions. Journal of Financial Services Research, 42(1), 55–83. https://doi.org/10.1007/s10693-011-0117-8
  • Illing, M., & Liu, Y. (2006). Measuring financial stress in a developed country: An application to Canada. Journal of Financial Stability, 2(3), 243–265. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jfs.2006.06.002
  • Kanno, M. (2015). Assessing systemic risk using interbank exposures in the global banking system. Journal of Financial Stability, 20, 105–130. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jfs.2015.08.006
  • Lux, T. (2015). Emergence of a Core-Periphery structure in a simple dynamic model of the interbank market. Journal of Economic Dynamics & Control, 52, 11–23. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jedc.2014.09.038
  • Memmel, C., Sachs, A., & Stein, I., (2011). Contagion at the interbank market with stochastic LGB. Discussion paper series 2: Banking and Financial studies No.06/2011.Deutsche Bundesbank Research Centre.
  • Osadume, R. C., & Mbachu, A. U. (2017). Impact of global financial crisis on Nigerian economy (2000-2015). International Journal of Economics and Financial Management, 2(1),1–19. https://iiardpub.org
  • Rogers, L. C., & Veraart, L. A. (2013). Failure and Rescue in an Interbank Network. Management Science, 59(4), 882–898. https://doi.org/10.1287/mnsc.1120.1569
  • Schwarz, S. L., (2008) Systemic risk. Duke law school legal studies paper, Duke University 163.
  • Sedunov, J. (2016). What is the systemic risk exposure of financial institutions? Journal of Financial Stability, 24, 71–87. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jfs.2016.04.005
  • Tarashev, N., Borio, C., & Tsatsaronis, K. (2010). Attributing Systemic Risk to Individual Institutions, Working Paper No 308, BIS, Basel.
  • Upper, C. (2011). Simulation methods to assess the danger of contagion in interbank networks. Journal of Financial Stability, 7(3), 111–125. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jfs.2010.12.001
  • Xu,T.,He,J.,& Li,S.(2016).A dynamic network model for Interbank Market. Physica A:Statistical Mechanics and its applications,463,131-138