703
Views
0
CrossRef citations to date
0
Altmetric
COGNITIVE & EXPERIMENTAL PSYCHOLOGY

The effect of challenging people’s fundamental assumptions about a task: Introducing uncertainty for reducing overprecision

, &
Article: 2196102 | Received 16 Aug 2022, Accepted 23 Mar 2023, Published online: 09 Apr 2023

References

  • Alpert, M., & Raiffa, H. (1982). A progress report on the training of probability assessors. In D. Kahneman, P. Slovic, & A. Tversky (Eds.), Judgement under uncertainty: Heuristics and biases (pp. 294–14). Cambridge University Press. https://doi.org/10.1017/CBO9780511809477.022
  • Arkes, H. R., Wortmann, R. L., Saville, P. D., & Harkness, A. R. (1981). Hindsight bias among physicians weighing the likelihood of diagnoses. The Journal of Applied Psychology, 66(2), 252–254.‏. https://doi.org/10.1037/0021-9010.66.2.252
  • Ben David, I., Graham, J. R., & Harvey, C. R. (2013). Managerial miscalibration. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 128(4), 1547–1584.‏. https://doi.org/10.1093/qje/qjt023
  • Camchong, J., Goodie, A. S., McDowell, J. E., Gilmore, C. S., & Clementz, B. A. (2007). A cognitive neuroscience approach to studying the role of overconfidence in problem gambling. Journal of Gambling Studies, 23(2), 185–199.‏. https://doi.org/10.1007/s10899-006-9033-5
  • Camerer, C. F., Ho, T. H., & Chong, J. K. (2004). A cognitive hierarchy model of games. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 119(3), 861–898.‏. https://doi.org/10.1162/0033553041502225
  • Carter, E. E. (1971). The behavioral theory of the firm and top-level corporate decisions. Administrative Science Quarterly, 16(4), 413–429. https://doi.org/10.2307/2391762
  • Chong, J. K., Ho, T. H., & Camerer, C. (2016). A generalized cognitive hierarchy model of games. Games and Economic Behavior, 99, 257–274.‏. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.geb.2016.08.007
  • Christensen-Szalanski, J. J., & Bushyhead, J. B. (1981). Physicians’ use of probabilistic information in a real clinical setting. Journal of Experimental Psychology Human Perception and Performance, 7(4), 928–935.‏. https://doi.org/10.1037/0096-1523.7.4.928
  • Collet, F. (2009). Does habitus matter? A comparative review of Bourdieu’s habitus and Simon’s bounded rationality with some implications for economic sociology. Sociological Theory, 27(4), 419–434.‏. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1467-9558.2009.01356.x
  • Du, N., Budescu, D. V., Shelly, M. K., & Omer, T. C. (2011). The appeal of vague financial forecasts. Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes, 114(2), 179–189.‏. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.obhdp.2010.10.005
  • Ferreira, A. P. R. B., Ferreira, R. F., Rajgor, D., Shah, J., Menezes, A., Pietrobon, R., & Fretheim, A. (2010). Clinical reasoning in the real world is mediated by bounded rationality: Implications for diagnostic clinical practice guidelines. Plos One, 5(4), e10265. https://doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0010265
  • Fischhoff, B., Slovic, P., & Lichtenstein, S. (1978). Fault trees: Sensitivity of estimated failure probabilities to problem representation. Journal of Experimental Psychology Human Perception and Performance, 4(2), 330–344.‏. https://doi.org/10.1037/0096-1523.4.2.330
  • Giardini, F., Coricelli, G., Joffily, M., & Sirigu, A. (2008). Overconfidence in predictions as an effect of desirability bias. In M. Abdellaoui & J. D. Hey (Eds.), Advances in Decision Making under Risk and Uncertainty (pp (pp. 163–180). Springer. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-540-68437-4_11
  • Gigerenzer, G. (2020). What is bounded rationality? In V. Ricardo (Ed.), Routledge Handbook of Bounded Rationality (pp. 55–69). Routledge.‏. https://doi.org/10.4324/9781315658353
  • Gopher, D., Weil, M., & Siegel, D. (1989). Practice under changing priorities: An approach to training of complex skills. Acta Psychologica, 71(1–3), 147–179. https://doi.org/10.1016/0001-6918(89)90007-3
  • Hill, L. D., Gray, J. J., Carter, M. M., & Schulkin, J. (2005). Obstetrician-gynecologists’ decision making about the diagnosis of major depressive disorder and premenstrual dysphoric disorder. Journal of Psychosomatic Obstetrics & Gynecology, 26(1), 41–51.‏. https://doi.org/10.1080/01443610400023023
  • Hirt, E. R., & Markman, K. D. (1995). Multiple explanation: A consider-an-alternative strategy for debiasing judgments. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 69(6), 1069.‏. https://doi.org/10.1037/0022-3514.69.6.1069
  • Jacob, M., & Hochstein, S. (2008). SET recognition as a window to perceptual and cognitive processes. Perception & Psychophysics, 70(7), 1165–1184.‏. https://doi.org/10.3758/PP.70.7.1165
  • Kahneman, D. (2003). Maps of bounded rationality: Psychology for behavioral economics. The American Economic Review, 93(5), 1449–1475.‏. https://doi.org/10.1257/000282803322655392
  • Klayman, J., Soll, J. B., Gonzalez-Vallejo, C., & Barlas, S. (1999). Overconfidence: It depends on how, what, and whom you ask. Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes, 79(3), 216–247.‏. https://doi.org/10.1006/obhd.1999.2847
  • Koriat, A. (1993). How do we know that we know? The accessibility model of the feeling of knowing. Psychological Review, 100(4), 609–639.‏. https://doi.org/10.1037/0033-295X.100.4.609
  • Koriat, A., & Bjork, R. A. (2005). Illusions of competence in monitoring one’s knowledge during study. Journal of Experimental Psychology Learning, Memory, and Cognition, 31(2), 187–194.‏. https://doi.org/10.1037/0278-7393.31.2.187
  • Koriat, A., Lichtenstein, S., & Fischhoff, B. (1980). Reasons for confidence. Journal of Experimental Psychology Human Learning and Memory, 6(2), 107–118.‏. https://doi.org/10.1037/0278-7393.6.2.107
  • Koriyama, Y., & Ozkes, A. I. (2021). Inclusive cognitive hierarchy. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 186, 458–480.‏. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jebo.2021.04.016
  • Makridakis, S., Hogarth, R. M., & Gaba, A. (2009). Forecasting and uncertainty in the economic and business world. International Journal of Forecasting, 25(4), 794–812.‏. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ijforecast.2009.05.012
  • Moore, D. A., & Healy, P. J. (2008). The trouble with overconfidence. Psychological Review, 115(2), 502–517.‏. https://doi.org/10.1037/0033-295X.115.2.502
  • Moore, D. A., Tenney, E. R., & Haran, U. (2015). Overprecision in judgment. In G. Keren & G. Wu (Eds.), The Wiley Blackwell handbook of judgment and decision making (pp. 182–209). Wiley‏. https://doi.org/10.1002/9781118468333.ch6
  • Morecroft, J. D. (1983). System dynamics: Portraying bounded rationality. Omega, 11(2), 131–142.‏. https://doi.org/10.1016/0305-0483(83)90002-6
  • Newell, K. M. (1991). Motor skill acquisition. Annual Review of Psychology, 42, 213–237. https://doi.org/10.1146/annurev.ps.42.020191.001241
  • Nyamsuren, E., & Taatgen, N. A. (2013a). The effect of visual representation style in problem-solving: A perspective from cognitive processes. Plos One, 8(11), e80550.‏. https://doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0080550
  • Nyamsuren, E., & Taatgen, N. A. (2013b). SET as an instance of a real‐world visual‐cognitive task. Cognitive Science, 37(1), 146–175.‏. https://doi.org/10.1111/cogs.12001
  • Nyamsuren, E., & Taatgen, N. A. (2013c). The synergy of top-down and bottom-up attention in complex task: Going beyond saliency models. Proceedings of the 35th annual conference of the cognitive science society, Austin, TX. vol. 35, pp. 3181–3186.‏
  • Sanchez, C., & Dunning, D. (2020). Decision fluency and overconfidence among beginners. Decision, 7(3), 225–237.‏. https://doi.org/10.1037/dec0000122
  • Scheinkman, J. A., & Xiong, W. (2003). Overconfidence and speculative bubbles. The Journal of Political Economy, 111(6), 1183–1220.‏. https://doi.org/10.1086/378531
  • Seagull, F. J., & Gopher, D. (1997). Training head movement in visual scanning: An embedded approach to the development of piloting skills with helmet-mounted displays. Journal of Experimental Psychology Applied, 3, 163–180. https://doi.org/10.1037/1076-898X.3.3.163
  • Simon, H. A. (1972). Theories of bounded rationality. Decision and Organization, 1(1), 161–176.‏.
  • Simon, H. A. (1990). Bounded rationality. In J. Eatwell, M. Milgate, & P. Newman (Eds.), Utility and probability (pp. 15–18). Palgrave Macmillan.‏. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-1-349-20568-4_5
  • Soll, J. B., & Klayman, J. (2004). Overconfidence in interval estimates. Journal of Experimental Psychology Learning, Memory, and Cognition, 30(2), 299–314.‏. https://doi.org/10.1037/0278-7393.30.2.299
  • Stanovich, K. E., & West, R. F. (2000). Individual differences in reasoning: Implications for the rationality debate? The Behavioral and Brain Sciences, 23(5), 645–665.‏ https://doi.org/10.1017/S0140525X00003435
  • Taatgen, N. A., van Oploo, M., Braaksma, J., & Niemantsverdriet, J. (2003). How to construct a believable opponent using cognitive modeling in the game of SET. Proceedings of the fifth international conference on cognitive modeling, Bamberg, Germany. (pp. 201–206). ‏Universitätsverlag Bamberg.
  • Travalos, A. K., & Pratt, J. (1995). Temporal locus of knowledge of result: A meta-analytic review. Perceptual and Motor Skills, 80(1), 3–14. https://doi.org/10.2466/pms.1995.80.1.3
  • Yechiam, E., Erev, I., & Gopher, D. (2001). On the potential value and limitations of emphasis change and other exploration-enhancing training methods. Journal of Experimental Psychology Applied, 7(4), 277–285. https://doi.org/10.1037/1076-898X.7.4.277
  • Yuviler-Gavish, N., Faran, D., & Berman, M. (2020). The effect of complexity on training for exploration of non-intuitive rules in theory of mind. Journal of Cognitive Enhancement, 4, 323–332. https://do.org/10.1007/s41465-019-00158-z‏